385readings(X) Spring 2011

 

Economists Say Europe Faces Low Growth for a Decade

By Luca Di Leo

Europe’s currency project will probably survive, but the price paid by the euro zone area is likely to be dismal economic growth for the next decade.

The verdict comes from economists gathered here from around the world for the annual meetings of the American Economic Association, which run Jan. 7 to Jan. 9.

“The most probable scenario is that Europe will just muddle through,” said Pascal Petit, from the Centre d’Economie de Paris Nord of the University of Paris.

With European countries forced to take austerity measures to stem market fears about surging public debt levels and a central bank focused more on controlling inflation than boosting growth, economists believe the 17-country area cannot escape continued low growth.

The “catastrophic” scenario outlined by Petit, in which the euro disintegrates, is unlikely because the costs would be too high for all the countries involved. An “optimistic” outcome, in which Europe overhauls its institutions and allows for more fiscal unity, also has a small chance of making it because better-off countries like Germany don’t want to pay for the fiscal profligacy of countries like Greece.

Last year, high sovereign debt levels in Greece and a banking crisis in Ireland forced both countries into tapping a trillion-dollar rescue fund set up by the European Union, with help from the International Monetary Fund. Some analysts fear Portugal and even Spain–the euro bloc’s fourth-largest economy–could stumble soon.

Both countries are expected to have to come to market with big bond deals. Spain’s central and regional governments, for example, will need to raise roughly EUR200 billion in 2011 and the country’s banks an additional 90 billion euros, according to Moody’s Investors Service.

Although there could be renewed tensions, European leaders are expected to find ways to ensure the common currency survives, because giving up would just be too costly. It would undermine 60 years of political efforts to build a united and peaceful Europe, and could cause unpredictable economic and financial disruption in a region whose trade and banking systems have become deeply intertwined since the euro was created in 1999.

“The euro is more than just a currency. A united Europe is the guarantor for our peace and our freedom. Germany needs Europe and our common currency, for our own good, and for coping with global challenges,” German Chancellor Angela Merkel said in her televised address to the nation marking the start of the New Year.

A.G. Malliaris, an economics professor at the Loyola University Chicago, sees only a 5.0% chance that the euro won’t make it. University of Cambridge economist John Eatwell also believes Europe’s single currency will eventually scrape through–even though the cost will be dismal economic growth for years to come.

 

 

Raising the Red Flag on Red Capitalism

Scratch the surface and China's economic model is less impressive than it looks.

By RICK CAREW

The conventional wisdom, propagated by senior businessmen, pundits and policy makers, holds that the 21st century is China's for the taking. The wise leaders in Beijing, we're led to believe, sailed through the financial crisis with deft management. They benefit from a long-term view that eludes their American and European counterparts. Growth is steaming along at nearly 10% and the global slowdown barely registered. The counterpoint, sometimes implicit and sometimes explicit, is that China's rise comes at the cost of America's decline.

So pervasive has this view become that any effort to examine whether it's actually true comes as a breath of fresh air. "Red Capitalism" is such a work. Authors Carl E. Walter and Fraser J.T. Howie, both investment bankers, argue that China isn't so different from other economies nor so immune from normal economic laws as cheerleaders argue. An examination of the financial system—or "how China's political elite manages money and the country's economy," as the authors put it—offers a useful lens through which to view much broader issues.

A striking observation is that foreigners (and perhaps Chinese policy makers too) have become so entranced by the large amounts of money flowing through the economy that they often forget to follow it. Noting only that China has produced six of the world's 15 largest initial public offerings since 2007 might create the impression that the country is developing a capitalistic financial market capable of intermediating its vast savings into a productive corporate sector. Last year, IPOs by Chinese companies reached $105 billion, 37% of global IPO volume.

What gets forgotten is just how "public" these offerings are—for IPOs within China, the majority of the investment capital comes from other state-owned companies rather than the private sector. And in an environment where regulators carefully manage the supply of new shares coming to market, it helps to be a state-owned company if you want to secure permission to list. Hence the stock market that's presented as evidence of China's capitalist transformation is in reality a merry-go-round for circulating money from one state-owned enterprise to another.

View Full Image

 

 

Red Capitalism

Carl E. Walter and Fraser J.T. Howie
Wiley, 250 pages, $29.95

The authors return again and again to the notion that while Beijing has embraced the form of market-based reform, the substance remains elusive. This has many implications. One relates to who's in charge of the Chinese economy. If reforms truly were leading to a more market-based system, one would expect a growing market for corporate control resulting from a wider dispersal of ownership. China would be witnessing more contested board elections, hostile takeover attempts and the like. This has not happened. Instead, the management of listed companies continues to be selected based on political criteria by China's Communist Party. Minority shareholders get no say, merely a ticket to ride.

Then there's that other crucial ingredient of a modern economy (recent financial crisis notwithstanding), the debt market. "Like highways, new airport terminals or CCTV's ultra-modern office building in Beijing, it exists because the Party believes bond markets are a necessary symbol of economic modernity," Messrs. Walter and Howie write.

Yet dig a little deeper and it becomes clear that this market is not allowed to perform its traditional role of pricing risk to facilitate the efficient flow of capital. It would be almost heretical for Chinese banks to ascribe riskiness to other state firms' debt, so the bond market simply doesn't attempt to price risk.

All well and good, but then again Beijing's current claim is that it is not trying to be like the Western capitalists—who it says failed so miserably to avert the financial crisis. Is it possible that Beijing's model, whatever its precise nature, will work?

It has certainly been profitable, up to a point, for foreigners. Chinese IPOs have no trouble attracting foreign investors keen to bet on the country's growth story. And Western banks, such as those that employ Messrs. Walter and Howie, have made millions upon millions of dollars piecing together bits of Chinese ministries into "corporations" to list.

Yet longer-term viability is another matter. China is not "a market economy, but a carefully balanced social mechanism built around the particular interests of the revolutionary families who constitute the political elite," the authors conclude. They liken the economy to a "family-run business," both figuratively, given its insularity, and literally, given the role of well-connected scions. As with any family business, that can be a blessing—if the "patriarch" is an expert in the field—or a curse—if an uninterested or unintelligent heir takes over. And the switch from one mode to the other can happen very suddenly.

How well the current ruling "family" understands the business is an open question, but there are signs it may not. "It appears the Party mistakenly believes its own advertising about its banks being rich and strong," Messrs. Walter and Howie write. "The absence of a strong leader is a weakness that allows the special interest groups to take advantage." The signs are all around us, and especially in Beijing's recent propensity for arrogance on the world economic stage.

That could be a ruinous mistake. The authors fret over unacknowledged bad loans piling up within the system (which implies leaders have been rampantly misallocating capital), and they estimate total public debt of about 76% of GDP, a very high figure for a developing country. With a rapidly aging population (more than 200 million people will be over the age of 65 by 2020) and weak social safety net, China can ill afford a banking crisis any time in the next decade. If and when one comes, Beijing could rue the many days when it resisted creating a more resilient, genuinely capitalist market.

Messrs. Walter and Howie will do little to dissuade the vast majority of foreign businessmen who are bullish on China. Nor are they likely to awaken its financial stewards to take action on the brewing problems below the surface. Perhaps China's cheerleaders are correct that China really is different. But after reading "Red Capitalism," and given the long, failed history of other claims to economic exceptionalism, is that a prudent bet to make?

Mr. Carew is a former Asia M&A reporter for The Wall Street Journal.

 

 

The $6.50 Trade War

A few facts about China trade for the new Congress to consider.

No sooner has a new Congress arrived in Washington than the anti-China-trade rhetoric has started anew. Senator Charles Schumer, whose Democrats still control his chamber, has said he plans to re-introduce legislation to punish China for its "currency manipulation." Tim Murphy, a Pennsylvania Republican, may push similar legislation he co-sponsored in the past, Reuters reports.

Legislative efforts face an uphill climb. Republican leaders in the House, including Speaker John Boehner, have voted against China currency bills in the past. But that doesn't make the anti-China fervor in parts of Washington irrelevant. Quite the opposite.

Leaders face many decisions on how best to put the American economy back on a growth track. To the extent that Congressional protectionists will present Chinese exporters as a threat to American prosperity despite all the other more pressing problems America faces, the argument over China's exchange-rate policy is a distraction the economy can't afford.

***

How much of a distraction is suggested by a paper out last month from the Asian Development Bank Institute. Economists Yuqing Xing and Neal Detert examined the supply chain of the iPhone to reach a surprising conclusion: Technically, the iPhone contributes to America's trade deficit with China.

The basic explanation is that data on bilateral trade are calculated assuming that the entire value of a traded good is created in the exporting country. If that ever made sense, it certainly doesn't in a global economy marked by increasingly complex supply chains.

In the case of the iPhone, Messrs. Xing and Detert note that the device was invented in America by an American company, Apple. The components are manufactured, either inside or out of China, by companies based in several other countries. The only part of the entire process that is unambiguously "Chinese" is the final assembly—a process that, in the estimation of Messrs. Xing and Detert, adds only $6.50 to the $178.96 wholesale value of an iPhone.

View Full Image

 

Associated Press

Yet that entire $178.96 value ends up attributed to China in the calculation of trade statistics. As a consequence, the iPhone contributed nearly $1 billion to China's bilateral trade surplus with America in 2008, and nearly $2 billion in 2009, the authors of this study conclude. If the trade data had been based solely on the $6.50 cost of assembling each unit, the iPhone would have added only $34 million and $73 million in those years, respectively, to China's surplus.

The ADBI study ought to be required reading on Capitol Hill. Most importantly, it raises the question of how much anyone really knows about what America's trade with China is. Critics of trade data, including us, have long asserted that bilateral statistics are misleading at best. As the bilateral trade deficit with China grew, deficits with South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore declined, confirming that China's comparative advantage lies in the assembly into finished products of components manufactured around the region, due to its low-wage, low-skilled labor.

The main potential flaw in the report is that Messrs. Xing and Detert may not have been able to account for the source of some of the inputs. While many of the companies that supply iPhone components are American, Japanese, Korean or German, those companies may in turn manufacture some of the components in China.

Yet even so, those companies would have their own mix of intellectual property developed outside China. It may be impossible ever to say precisely how much value China adds to the iPhone, or to any other product. Lawmakers should think twice about basing important policy decisions on such incomplete data.

Crucially, the trade data also miss the broader economic impact of "imports" like the iPhone. The benefits are clear and large, though hard to quantify precisely. First there are the gains to Apple itself. The ADBI study examines only the composition of the $178.96 manufacturing cost of the iPhone. The handsets typically retail for as much as 50% to 100% more than that. The difference consists of the value of Apple's intellectual property in having invented the iPhone, and also the value of marketing in persuading consumers to buy the hot new thing.

The ADBI study doesn't break down that figure, but others have performed similar research in the past. Economists at the Personal Computing Industry Center attempted in 2007 to estimate who profits from the iPod and how. They estimated that for an iPod retailing for $299, retailer and distributor margins account for $75 and Apple's own margin accounted for $80. In other words, more than half the retail price accrued to American companies—and their employees and shareholders—in some form.

None of these studies accounts for another huge way such imports drive growth by spurring innovative new businesses. Telecom companies like AT&T and, now, Verizon have profited by being able to offer data services to iPhone-toting consumers. Countless programmers around the world are now devising applications for the iPhone and iPad, which offer many businesses a convenient new way to reach potential customers.

***

All of which illustrates the basic truth that trade has always benefited the American economy. Congress can't afford to forget that, no matter how much Members would like to scapegoat Chinese factories for Washington's own policy mistakes.

So rather than launching a trade war with China over $6.50, here's a better agenda for the 112th Congress: Focus on policies that will help Americans and U.S. companies better capitalize on a global economy. That includes better tax policies to reward investment and entrepreneurship; environmental regulation that does not discourage manufacturing in America when it would make business sense; health-care policies that don't deter hiring; and free trade to let Americans import goods like iPhones that will spur new growth.

 

 

So Much For Cuban Economic Reform

The Communist Party affirms that 'central planning and not the market will be supreme.'

By JOSé AZEL

With his characteristic intellectual wit, Cuban writer Carlos Alberto Montaner defines communism as "the time countries waste between capitalism and capitalism." By this account, the Cuban government is now in its 52nd year of wasted time waiting for prosperity.

Much has been made of economic reforms promised by Raúl Castro, including by the Cuban president himself. "We can either rectify the situation," Gen. Castro recently stated, "or we will run out of time walking on the edge of the abyss, and we will sink." But one look at the economic platform for the VI Congress of the Communist Party of Cuba, now scheduled for April 2011, and it's clear nothing much will change.

The "Draft Guidelines for Economic and Social Policy"—a 32-page document that proposes to chart Cuba's economic future—affirms that "the new economic policy will correspond with the principle that only socialism [i.e., Cuban communism] is capable of conquering the difficulties."

The document persistently emphasizes Gen. Castro's militaristic themes of increased efficiency, discipline and control. It insists, for example, on setting prices according to the dictates of central planning. It also insists that any new "nonstate" (private sector) economic activities not be allowed to lead to the "concentration of property" (that is, the accumulation of wealth). There is no interest in introducing the market socialism of a Deng Xiaoping, who famously told China's people in 1984 that "to get rich is glorious."

It is not surprising that Raúl and his fellow generals are more comfortable with the chain of command of a centrally planned economy than with the vicissitudes of a market economy. More baffling is their failure to understand core principles of economic development.

View Full Image

Associated Press

Raul Castro, president of Cuba, and commander of its armed forces, will affirm that "central planning and not the market will be supreme."

After much debate and with trepidation, the Cuban economic "reformers" have decided to permit the 500,000 to 1,300,000 Cubans being fired from state jobs to solicit permits to become self-employed in certain activities. It is instructive to examine a handful of the 178 trades and professions that are supposed to help rescue the economy.

Trade No. 23 will be the purchase and sale of used books. Trade 29 is an attendant of public bathrooms (presumably for tips); 34 is a palm-tree pruner (apparently other trees will still be pruned by the state). Trade 49 is covering buttons with fabric; 61 is shining shoes; 62 is cleaning spark plugs; 69 is a typist; 110 is the repair of box springs (not to be confused with 116, the repair of mattresses). Trade 124 is umbrella repairs; 125 is refilling of disposable cigarette lighters; 150 is fortune-telling with tarot cards; 156 is being a dandy (technical definition unknown, maybe a male escort?); 158 is peeling natural fruit (separate from 142, selling fruit in kiosks).

This bizarre list of permitted private-sector activities will not drive economic development. But it does reveal the regime's totalitarian mindset. Here Cuban technocrats foreshadow the degree of control they intend to impose by listing the legal activities with specificity. These are not reforms to unleash the market's "invisible hand" but to reaffirm the Castros' clenched fist. One does not have to be an economist to appreciate that the refilling of disposable cigarette lighters, for example, will not contribute in any measure to economic development.

In his economic dream land of surrealist juxtapositions, Raúl believes that improved state management is the way to save the communist system. The desire for control by the military and the Communist Party of every aspect of Cuban life is antithetical to the individual liberty and empowerment necessary to bring about an economic renaissance.

Mr. Azel, a senior scholar at the Institute for Cuban and Cuban-American Studies, University of Miami, is author of "Mañana in Cuba" (Authorhouse, 2010).

 

Developing Nations Fight Inflation

Price Jumps, Especially on Food, Threaten Growth Engines ; A Contrast With West

By ALEX FRANGOS, JOHN LYONS And VIBHUTI AGARWAL

Inflation is spreading across the world's largest emerging nations, leaving a noisy rattle in what have been the engines of global growth in recent years.

Central banks in Brazil, Russia, India and China, the fast-growing so-called BRIC nations now responsible for nearly a fifth of global economic activity, have all raised interest rates in recent weeks, and are testing more exotic measures to stanch rising prices, especially for food: India and Russia banned exports of onions and wheat, respectively, while China has promised price controls on items such as cooking oil.

View Full Image

Reuters

A farmer transports vegetables on an improvised tricycle toward a market in Kolkata Thursday. India's food inflation has picked up recently.

Brazil said Friday that its 2010 inflation rate had risen to 5.9%, its fastest rate in six years, raising the chances the nation will push its already sky-high interest rates even higher, potentially hampering growth.

To be sure, Brazil's single-digit inflation rate is a universe away from the hyperinflation it suffered in the early 1990s. And some analysts say fears of an emerging-market inflation spiral are overstated, with current inflation rates still below where they were when prices peaked before the financial crisis in 2008.

Still, the inflation trend is creating tricky policy headaches for officials from Beijing to New Delhi, including fears that rising food prices in these mostly poor nations may jeopardize social stability.

"Inflation is one of the major risks for this year," says Nicholas Kwan, economist for Standard Chartered in Hong Kong.

The accelerating price gains in the developing world contrast sharply with low inflation rates in Europe and the U.S. and persistent price declines in Japan. The divergence is partly a byproduct of the stronger economic recoveries achieved by emerging nations compared with sluggish growth in the West.

Such diverging economic fortunes are complicating inflation-fighting efforts in the developing world, economists say.

Leaders in Brazil and other countries complain that the U.S. Federal Reserve's decision to pump $600 billion into the economy promotes commodity inflation and asset bubbles by weakening the dollar. U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke said Friday the stimulus measure wasn't adding to inflation.

View Full Image

A better-than-expected recovery in the U.S. could fuel inflation by sending a jolt of demand through the global supply chain, causing economies already running at full capacity to overheat, economists say.

"We are arriving at a juncture where policy requirements in emerging economies will be overwhelmed by advanced-economy policies," said Cornell University economist Eswar Shanker Prasad a senior fellow at the Brookings Institution.

Brazil illustrates the case. The South American giant has set some of the world's highest interest rates in order to keep a lid on inflation as economic growth nears 7% and amid rising government spending to lift the poor.

The 10.75% rate has attracted a flood of speculative investment from the U.S. and Japan, where monetary policy is loose in order to spur growth.

As a result, the Brazilian real has soared more than 35% since 2009 against the U.S. dollar, making exports less competitive and making domestic manufacturers vulnerable to less expensive imports. To avoid raising rates further, Brazil is trying other measures such as restricting credit by raising bank reserve requirements.

The issue is a major test for the brand-new government of Dilma Rousseff. Though Ms. Rousseff campaigned on expanded welfare spending, she is now contemplating politically risky spending restraints to shrink deficits and cool the economy.

In developing countries, price rises, especially for food, can have a big impact. Because incomes are lower than in the developed world, food and energy make up substantial part of household spending—and most emerging-market inflation measures. Food prices globally hit an all-time high in December, according to a United Nations index.

And there are signs that the increase in food prices is not abating as some had expected, and that price increases are creeping into the broader part of some economies. China's 5.1% consumer-price inflation rate in November was driven mostly by food prices, which rose 11.7%. But the so-called core inflation rate, which excludes energy and food, rose as well, up 1.9% from a year earlier

China has introduced a raft of measures to tamp prices, including two interest-rate increases, a slightly stronger currency, tighter bank lending, price controls, and efforts to clamp down on illegal speculation in food. Chinese officials have signaled they will continue to tighten to tame inflation.

Kong Ong, Hong Kong owner of Headquarters Industrial Ltd., which makes more than a million hats a year on the mainland for export to the U.S. and Germany, says rising prices material prices and wages are concerns. Cotton, which is 30-40% of his costs, hit record highs last year. Prevailing wages have risen and he expects them to go up again this year. And living costs are keeping migrant workers closer to home.

"When the inflation rate is too high, workers don't want to come to the big cities because the big cities the living cost is too high," he says. In India, where high food prices drove inflation for much of 2010, expectations had been that a solid harvest for rice and other staples would ease the pressure. But the latest government data show the food situation hasn't been resolved and food-price inflation has jumped in India of late, reaching 18% in the week ended Dec. 25, according to figures released this week. Economists say the Reserve Bank of India, after raising interest rates six times in 2010, will almost certainly tighten again when it meets Jan. 25 for a regular policy meeting.

India's economy is expected to grow by 8.75% in the year ending March 31, according to an International Monetary Fund report issued Thursday. But inflation is threatening to undermine the economic gains for hundreds of millions of poor and less well-off Indians.The government has scrambled to take measures to alleviate the food-price increases, for instance banning the export of onions.

What's more, officials across emerging markets are concerned that price increases may erode the hard-won credibility of central banks and lead to increased inflation expectations among locals.

Amrith Mathur, a 36-year-old software engineer buying vegetables at a wholesale market in New Delhi Friday morning, says the price rises have virtually canceled out salary increases.

"I got a paltry increment of 5% in salary after a gap of two years this year, but thanks to the prices of essential commodities which have skyrocketed, the rise is as good as nil," he said. "How can the government achieve their tall growth target of 9%-10% if the people's spending power is getting lesser and lesser by the day," he said.

In Russia, summer droughts sent wheat prices skyrocketing and undermined the government's goal of keeping inflation in the 6%-7% range in 2010. Russia reported this week that consumer prices rose a faster-than-expected 1% in December from November and 8.7% over the past year, raising expectations for interest-rate increases in the coming months.

Other large emerging economies also have seen prices rise faster than expected in recent months. Peru surprised with a rate increase this week, and Mexico reported faster-than-expected inflation of 4.4%. Thailand is expected to raise interest rates next week. South Korea has also said it will unveil a package of policies to tackle rising prices next week.

Indonesia's consumer-inflation rate hit 7% in December, a 20-month high and the fourth time in six months prices outpaced the central bank's 4%-6% target. The central bank has yet to raise interest rates since the recovery began in 2009, figuring higher rates will have little effect on food prices.

—Ira Iosebashvili and Robb Stewart contributed to this article.

Write to Alex Frangos at alex.frangos@wsj.com, John Lyons at john.lyons@wsj.com and Vibhuti Agarwal at vibhuti.agarwal@wsj.com

 

« Column on TSA Wins “Sentence of the Day” Contest

Hungary Joins the Flat Tax Club »

Don’t Blame Ireland’s Mess on Low Corporate Tax Rates

November 18, 2010 by Dan Mitchell

Ireland is in deep fiscal trouble and the Germans and the French apparently want the politicians in Dublin to increase the nation’s 12.5 percent corporate tax rate as the price for being bailed out. This is almost certainly the cause of considerable smugness and joy in Europe’s high-tax nations, many of which have been very resentful of Ireland for enjoying so much prosperity in recent decades in part because of a low corporate tax burden.

But is there any reason to think Ireland’s competitive corporate tax regime is responsible for the nation’s economic crisis? The answer, not surprisingly, is no. Here’s a chart from one of Ireland’s top economists, looking at taxes and spending for past 27 years. You can see that revenues grew rapidly, especially beginning in the 1990s as the lower tax rates were implemented. The problem is that politicians spent every penny of this revenue windfall.

When the financial crisis hit a couple of years ago, tax revenues suddenly plummeted. Unfortunately, politicians continued to spend like drunken sailors. It’s only in the last year that they finally stepped on the brakes and began to rein in the burden of government spending. But that may be a case of too little, too late.

The second chart provides additional detail. Interestingly, the burden of government spending actually fell as a share of GDP between 1983 and 2000. This is not because government spending was falling, but rather because the private sector was growing even faster than the public sector.

This bit of good news (at least relatively speaking) stopped about 10 years ago. Politicians began to increase government spending at roughly the same rate as the private sector was expanding. While this was misguided, tax revenues were booming (in part because of genuine growth and in part because of the bubble) and it seemed like bigger government was a free lunch.

But big government is never a free lunch. Government spending diverts resources from the productive sector of the economy. This is now painfully apparent since there no longer is a revenue windfall to mask the damage.

There are lots of lessons to learn from Ireland’s fiscal/economic/financial crisis. There was too much government spending. Ireland also had a major housing bubble. And some people say that adopting the euro (the common currency of many European nations) helped create the current mess.

The one thing we can definitely say, though, is that lower tax rates did not cause Ireland’s problems. It’s also safe to say that higher tax rates will delay Ireland’s recovery. French and German politicians may think that’s a good idea, but hopefully Irish lawmakers have a better perspective.

 

i

 

http://www.cato-at-liberty.org/five-lessons-from-ireland/

Five Lessons from Ireland

Posted by Daniel J. Mitchell

The news is going from bad to worse for Ireland. The Irish Independent is reporting that the Swiss Central Bank no longer will accept Irish government bonds as collateral. The story also notes that one of the world’s largest bond firms, PIMCO, is no longer purchasing debt issued by the Irish government.

And this is happening even though (or perhaps because?) Ireland received a big bailout from the European Union and the International Monetary Fund (and the IMF’s involvement means American taxpayers are picking up part of the tab).

I’ve already commented on Ireland’s woes, and opined about similar problems afflicting the rest of Europe, but the continuing deterioration of the Emerald Isle deserves further analysis so that American policy makers hopefully grasp the right lessons. Here are five things we should learn from the mess in Ireland.

1. Bailouts Don’t Work — When Ireland’s government rescued depositors by bailing out the nation’s three big banks, they made a big mistake by also bailing out creditors such as bondholders. This dramatically increased the cost of the bank bailout and exacerbated moral hazard since investors are more willing to make inefficient and risky choices if they think governments will cover their losses. And because it required the government to incur a lot of additional debt, it also had the effect of destabilizing the nation’s finances, which then resulted in a second mistake — the bailout of Ireland by the European Union and IMF (a classic case of Mitchell’s Law, which occurs when one bad government policy leads to another bad government policy).

American policy makers already have implemented one of the two mistakes mentioned above. The TARP bailout went way beyond protecting depositors and instead gave unnecessary handouts to wealthy and sophisticated companies, executives, and investors. But something good may happen if we learn from the second mistake. Greedy politicians from states such as California and Illinois would welcome a bailout from Uncle Sam, but this would be just as misguided as the EU/IMF bailout of Ireland. The Obama Administration already provided an indirect short-run bailout as part of the so-called stimulus legislation, and this encouraged states to dig themselves deeper in a fiscal hole. Uncle Sam shouldn’t be subsidizing bad policy at the state level, and the mess in Europe is a powerful argument that this counter-productive approach should be stopped as soon as possible.

By the way, it’s worth noting that politicians and international bureaucracies behave as if government defaults would have catastrophic consequences, but Kevin Hassett of the American Enterprise Institute explains that there have been more than 200 sovereign defaults in the past 200 years and we somehow avoided Armageddon.

2. Excessive Government Spending Is a Path to Fiscal Ruin — The bailout of the banks obviously played a big role in causing Ireland’s fiscal collapse, but the government probably could have weathered that storm if politicians in Dublin hadn’t engaged in a 20-year spending spree.

The red line in the chart shows the explosive growth of government spending. Irish politicians got away with this behavior for a long time. Indeed, government spending as a share of GDP (the blue line) actually fell during the 1990s because the private sector was growing even faster than the public sector. This bit of good news (at least relatively speaking) stopped about 10 years ago. Politicians began to increase government spending at roughly the same rate as the private sector was expanding. While this was misguided, tax revenues were booming (in part because of genuine growth and in part because of the bubble) and it seemed like bigger government was a free lunch.

Eventually, however, the house of cards collapsed. Revenues dried up and the banks failed, but because the politicians had spent so much during the good times, there was no reserve during the bad times.

American politicians are repeating these mistakes. Spending has skyrocketed during the Bush-Obama year. We also had our version of a financial system bailout, though fortunately not as large as Ireland’s when measured as a share of economic output, so our crisis is likely to occur when the baby boom generation has retired and the time comes to make good on the empty promises to fund Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.

3. Low Corporate Tax Rates Are Good, but They Don’t Guarantee Economic Success if other Policies Are Bad — Ireland used to be a success story. They went from being the “Sick Man of Europe” in the early 1980s to being the “Celtic Tiger” earlier this century in large part because policy makers dramatically reformed fiscal policy. Government spending was capped in the late 1980 and tax rates were reduced during the 1990s. The reform of the corporate income tax was especially dramatic. Irish lawmakers reduced the tax rate from 50 percent all the way down to 12.5 percent.

This policy was enormously successful in attracting new investment, and Ireland’s government actually wound up collecting more corporate tax revenue at the lower rate. This was remarkable since it is only in very rare cases that the Laffer Curve means a tax cut generates more revenue for government (in the vast majority of cases, the Laffer Curve simply means that changes in taxable income will have revenue effects that offset only a portion of the revenue effects caused by the change in tax rates).

Unfortunately, good corporate tax policy does not guarantee good economic performance if the government is making a lot of mistakes in other areas. This is an apt description of what happened to Ireland. The silver lining to this sad story is that Irish politicians have resisted pressure from France and Germany and are keeping the corporate tax rate at 12.5 percent. The lesson for American policy makers, of course, is that low corporate tax rates are a very good idea, but don’t assume they protect the economy from other policy mistakes.

4. Artificially Low Interest Rates Encourage Bubbles — No discussion of Ireland’s economic problems would be complete without looking at the decision to join the common European currency. Adopting the euro had some advantages, such as not having to worry about changing money when traveling to many other European nations. But being part of Europe’s monetary union also meant that Ireland did not have flexible interest rates.

Normally, an economic boom drives up interest rates because the plethora of profitable opportunities leads investors demand more credit. But Ireland’s interest rates, for all intents and purposes, were governed by what was happening elsewhere in Europe, where growth was generally anemic. The resulting artificially low interest rates in Ireland helped cause a bubble, much as artificially low interest rates in America last decade led to a bubble.

But if America already had a bubble, what lesson can we learn from Ireland? The simple answer is that we should learn to avoid making the same mistake over and over again. Easy money is a recipe for inflation and/or bubbles. Simply stated, excess money has to go someplace and the long-run results are never pleasant. Yet Ben Bernanke and the Federal Reserve have launched QE2, a policy explicitly designed to lower interest rates in hopes of artificially juicing the economy.

5. Housing Subsidies Reduce Prosperity — Last but not least, Ireland’s bubble was worsened in part because politicians created an extensive system of preferences that tilted the playing field in the direction of real estate. The combination of these subsidies and the artificially low interest rates caused widespread malinvestment and Ireland is paying the price today.

Since we just endured a financial crisis caused in large part by a corrupt system of housing subsidies for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, American policy makers should have learned this lesson already. But as Thomas Sowell sagely observes, politicians are still fixated on somehow re-inflating the housing bubble. The lesson they should have learned is that markets should determine value, not politics.

Daniel J. Mitchell • January 5, 2011 @ 12:47 pm
Filed under: Finance, Banking & Monetary Policy; Government and Politics; International Economics and Development; Tax and Budget Policy
Tags: bailouts, big government, bubbles, corporate income tax, Easy Money, Euro, government spending, Housing, imf, Ireland, laffer curve, Malinvestment, monetary policy, subsidies

Share/Bookmark

 

 

Elinor Ostrom and Oliver Williamson win this year’s Nobel prize for economics

Economics focus

Oct 15th 2009 | from PRINT EDITION  The Economist

Illustration by Jac Depczyk

BUILDING economic models usually involves stripping the world down to its most essential features. But simple theories often struggle to explain the way things really work. Elinor Ostrom of Indiana University and Oliver Williamson of the University of California at Berkeley, the winners of this year’s Nobel prize for economics, have both been honoured for recognising this complexity. Their research provides insights into economic institutions that play crucial roles in the real world, but to which economists have not paid enough attention.

In the case of Mr Williamson, that institution is the company. With hierarchical decision-making processes based on rules and authority, firms ought to be less efficient than decentralised market exchange based on relative prices, which is how standard economic theory assumes that transactions occur. So why do companies exist at all? This question was first addressed in 1937 by Ronald Coase, the winner of the 1991 Nobel prize for economics and the intellectual forefather of both of this year’s winners. Mr Coase argued that all economic transactions are costly—even in competitive markets, there are costs associated with figuring out the right price. The most efficient institutional arrangement for carrying out a particular economic activity would be the one that minimised transaction costs. This would often be the market. But using authority and rules within a firm would sometimes prove to be more efficient.

Mr Coase’s theory explained why companies existed but it was not specific enough to predict the conditions under which firms, or markets, would be the superior form of organisation. Clarifying this was Mr Williamson’s signal contribution. In a series of papers and books written between 1971 and 1985, he argued that the costs of completing transactions on spot markets increase with their complexity, and if they involve assets that are worth more within a relationship between two parties than outside it (a rear-view mirror made to the specifications of a particular car manufacturer, for example).

Related items


Related topics

Both these features make writing and enforcing contracts which take every possible eventuality into consideration difficult, or even impossible. At some point, therefore, it makes sense to conduct the associated transaction within a single legal entity rather than on a market. The car company might prefer to produce its rear-view mirrors in-house, for example, perhaps by buying the mirror company. This would reduce the time and resources spent haggling over profits, because decisions would simply be taken by fiat.

Mr Williamson’s theory helpfully specified measurable attributes of transactions that would make them more or less amenable to being conducted on markets. That meant his thinking could be tested against decisions by companies to integrate parts of their supply chain. It has held up remarkably well. Several studies find, for instance, that when an electricity generator can choose between the output of many nearby coalmines that produce coal of a particular quality, it tends to buy its coal on an open market. But if there is only one nearby mine that can be relied upon as a supplier, the electricity generator tends to own it. A transaction that could be done on the market moves into the firm.

According to Mr Williamson, one lesson from organisational theory is the importance of identifying common patterns of behaviour in seemingly disparate situations. That sums up the way Elinor Ostrom has spent her working life. The first woman to win a Nobel prize for economics, she studies the governance of “common resource pools”—such as pastures, fisheries or forests—to which more than one person has access. Unlike pure public goods such as the atmosphere, where one person’s use does not reduce the amount available to others, people deplete these resources when they use them. Standard economic models predict that in the absence of clearly defined property rights, such common resources will be overexploited, with individuals acting without regard for the effects of their actions on the overall pool. Overfishing or overgrazing (the “tragedy of the commons”) will result. Over time, stocks of the common resource will dwindle.

But in 40 years of studying how common resources—from lobster fisheries in Maine to irrigation systems in Nepal—are actually managed by communities, Ms Ostrom found that people often devise rather sophisticated systems of governance to ensure that these resources are not overused. These systems involve explicit rules about what people can use, what their responsibilities are, and how they will be punished if they break the rules. In particular, she found that self-governance often worked much better than an ill-informed government taking over and imposing sometimes clumsy, and often ineffective, rules. In this, she too shadows Mr Coase, who argued that those who advocated government ownership of common resources ignored the transaction costs associated with collecting taxes.

 

Tit for tat

One problem with the idea of the tragedy of the commons, Ms Ostrom found, was that it did not account for the fact that people sharing a pool of resources tend to interact repeatedly, making all sorts of clever punishments for wrongdoing feasible. Being able to threaten credible retaliation makes co-operation possible. This is the province of game theory, to which Ms Ostrom has contributed, both through formal modelling of what she found in the field and subsequent laboratory tests of her models.

Both Mr Williamson and Ms Ostrom have built on Mr Coase’s idea that all transactions have costs but that these costs will be minimised by different institutional arrangements in different situations. Their work uses methods and insights from fields that many economists are not sufficiently familiar with: detailed case studies, in the case of Ms Ostrom, a political scientist by training, and insights from the law in Mr Williamson’s case. Their win reminds economists that borders between disciplines, like those between the firm and the market, can be profitably crossed.

from PRINT EDITION | Finance and Economics

 

 

And more on Oliver Williamson (again, the PhD committee chair of Peter Klein, author of the blog post linked at the top) and Elinor Ostrom, winners of the 2009 Nobel Prize in economics:

Economics focus: Reality bites | The Economist

In the case of Mr Williamson, that institution is the company. With hierarchical decision-making processes based on rules and authority, firms ought to be less efficient than decentralised market exchange based on relative prices, which is how standard economic theory assumes that transactions occur. So why do companies exist at all? This question was first addressed in 1937 by Ronald Coase, the winner of the 1991 Nobel prize for economics and the intellectual forefather of both of this year’s winners. Mr Coase argued that all economic transactions are costly—even in competitive markets, there are costs associated with figuring out the right price. The most efficient institutional arrangement for carrying out a particular economic activity would be the one that minimised transaction costs. This would often be the market. But using authority and rules within a firm would sometimes prove to be more efficient.

Mr Coase’s theory explained why companies existed but it was not specific enough to predict the conditions under which firms, or markets, would be the superior form of organisation. Clarifying this was Mr Williamson’s signal contribution. In a series of papers and books written between 1971 and 1985, he argued that the costs of completing transactions on spot markets increase with their complexity, and if they involve assets that are worth more within a relationship between two parties than outside it (a rear-view mirror made to the specifications of a particular car manufacturer, for example).

Both these features make writing and enforcing contracts which take every possible eventuality into consideration difficult, or even impossible. At some point, therefore, it makes sense to conduct the associated transaction within a single legal entity rather than on a market. The car company might prefer to produce its rear-view mirrors in-house, for example, perhaps by buying the mirror company. This would reduce the time and resources spent haggling over profits, because decisions would simply be taken by fiat.

Mr Williamson’s theory helpfully specified measurable attributes of transactions that would make them more or less amenable to being conducted on markets. That meant his thinking could be tested against decisions by companies to integrate parts of their supply chain. It has held up remarkably well.
Several studies find, for instance, that when an electricity generator can choose between the output of many nearby coalmines that produce coal of a particular quality, it tends to buy its coal on an open market. But if there is only one nearby mine that can be relied upon as a supplier, the electricity generator tends to own it. A transaction that could be done on the market moves into the firm.

According to Mr Williamson, one lesson from organisational theory is the importance of identifying common patterns of behaviour in seemingly disparate situations. That sums up the way Elinor Ostrom has spent her working life. The first woman to win a Nobel prize for economics, she studies the governance of “common resource pools”—such as pastures, fisheries or forests—to which more than one person has access. Unlike pure public goods such as the atmosphere, where one person’s use does not reduce the amount available to others, people deplete these resources when they use them. Standard economic models predict that in the absence of clearly defined property rights, such common resources will be overexploited, with individuals acting without regard for the effects of their actions on the overall pool. Overfishing or overgrazing (the “tragedy of the commons”) will result. Over time, stocks of the common resource will dwindle.

But in 40 years of studying how common resources—from lobster fisheries in Maine to irrigation systems in Nepal—are actually managed by communities, Ms Ostrom found that people often devise rather sophisticated systems of governance to ensure that these resources are not overused. These systems involve explicit rules about what people can use, what their responsibilities are, and how they will be punished if they break the rules. In particular, she found that self-governance often worked much better than an ill-informed government taking over and imposing sometimes clumsy, and often ineffective, rules. In this, she too shadows Mr Coase, who argued that those who advocated government ownership of common resources ignored the transaction costs associated with collecting taxes.

Tit for tat

One problem with the idea of the tragedy of the commons, Ms Ostrom found, was that it did not account for the fact that people sharing a pool of resources tend to interact repeatedly, making all sorts of clever punishments for wrongdoing feasible. Being able to threaten credible retaliation makes co-operation possible. This is the province of game theory, to which Ms Ostrom has contributed, both through formal modelling of what she found in the field and subsequent laboratory tests of her models.

Both Mr Williamson and Ms Ostrom have built on Mr Coase’s idea that all transactions have costs but that these costs will be minimised by different institutional arrangements in different situations. . . .

 

http://www.american.com/archive/2010/december/human-nature-and-capitalism

Human Nature and Capitalism

Saturday, December 11, 2010

Filed under: Culture, Big Ideas, Public Square

The model of human nature one embraces will guide and shape everything else, from the economic system one prefers to the political system one supports.

At the core of every social, political, and economic system is a picture of human nature (to paraphrase 20th-century columnist Walter Lippmann). The suppositions we begin with—the ways in which that picture is developed—determine the lives we lead, the institutions we build, and the civilizations we create. They are the foundation stone.

Three Views of Human Nature

During the 18th century—a period that saw the advent of modern capitalism—there were several different currents of thought about the nature of the human person. Three models were particularly significant.

One model was that humans, while flawed, are perfectible. A second was that we are flawed, and fatally so; we need to accept and build our society around this unpleasant reality. A third view was that although human beings are flawed, we are capable of virtuous acts and self-government—that under the right circumstances, human nature can work to the advantage of the whole.

The first school included those who (representing the French Enlightenment) believed in man’s perfectibility and the pre-eminence of scientific rationalism. Their plans were grandiose, utopian, and revolutionary, aiming at “the universal regeneration of mankind” and the creation of a “New Man.”1

Advocates of free enterprise believe that creativity, enterprise, and ingenuity compose essential parts of human nature.

Such notions, espoused by Jean-Jacques Rousseau and other Enlightenment philosophes, heavily influenced a later generation of socialist thinkers. These theorists—Robert Owen, Charles Fourier, and Henri de Saint-Simon among them—believed that human nature can be as easily reshaped as hot wax. They considered human nature plastic and malleable, to the point that no fixed human nature existed to speak of; architects of a social system could, therefore, mold it into anything they imagined.

These theorists dreamed of a communal society, liberated from private property and free of human inequality. They articulated a theory of human nature and socioeconomic organization that eventually influenced capitalism’s most famous and bitter critic: the German philosopher, economist, and revolutionary Karl Marx.

The second current of thought, embodied in the writings of 17th-century Englishmen Thomas Hobbes and Bernard Mandeville, viewed human nature as more nearly the opposite: inelastic, brittle, and unalterable. And people were, at their core, antisocial beings.

Hobbes, for example, worried that people were ever in danger of lapsing into a pre-civilized state, “without a common power to keep them all in awe,” which, in turn, would lead to a hopeless existence, a “state of nature” characterized by “a war of every man, against every man.” It was, Hobbes wrote, a life “solitary, poor, nasty, brutish, and short.” To avoid this fate, one must submit to the authority of the state, what he termed the “Leviathan” (a monstrous, multi-headed sea creature mentioned in the Hebrew Bible). In the process, we would gain self-preservation, but at the expense of liberty.2

The third model of human nature is found in the thinking of the American founders. “If men were angels,” wrote James Madison, the father of the Constitution, in Federalist Paper No. 51, “no government would be necessary.” But Madison and the other founders knew men were not angels and would never become angels. They believed instead that human nature was mixed, a combination of virtue and vice, nobility and corruption. People were swayed by both reason and passion, capable of self-government but not to be trusted with absolute power. The founders’ assumption was that within every human heart, let alone among different individuals, are competing and sometimes contradictory moral impulses and currents.

A free market can also better our moral condition—not dramatically and not always, but often enough. It places a premium on thrift, savings, and investment.

This last view of human nature is consistent with and reflective of Christian teaching. The Scriptures teach that we are both made in the image of God and fallen creatures; in the words of Saint Paul, we can be “instruments of wickedness” as well as “instruments of righteousness.”3 All have sinned and fallen short of the glory of God, the Bible declares—yet it also tells us to be holy in all our conduct, to walk in His statutes, and not to grow weary in doing good. Human beings are capable of acts of squalor and acts of nobility; we can pursue vice and we can pursue virtue.

As for the matter of the state: Romans 13 makes clear that government is divinely sanctioned by God to preserve public order, restrain evil, and make justice possible. This, too, was a view shared by many of the founders. Government reflects human nature, they argued, “because the passions of men will not conform to the dictates of reason and justice without constraint.”4

The Anglo-Scottish Enlightenment philosophies of Adam Smith, David Hume, and Francis Hutcheson both informed and aligned with the views of the American founders and Christian teaching. Smith was himself a professor of moral philosophy; The Theory of Moral Sentiments5 preceded The Wealth of Nations.6 Smith and his compatriots did not believe in the perfectibility of human nature and thought it foolish to build any human institution on the possibility of attaining such perfection. Neither did they believe that human nature was irredeemably corrupt and devoid of virtue.

Self Interest: A Positive or Negative Human Characteristic?

The American founders believed, and capitalism rests on the belief, that people are driven by “self-interest” and the desire to better our condition. Self-interest is not necessarily bad; in fact, Smith believed, and capitalism presupposes, that the general welfare depends on allowing an individual to pursue his self-interest “as long as he does not violate the laws of justice.” When a person acts in his own interest, “he frequently promotes [the interest] of society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. ”7

Michel Guillaume Jean de Crèvecœur, among the first writers who attempted to explain the American frontier and the concept of the “American Dream” to a European audience, captured this view when he wrote:

The American ought therefore to love this country much better than that wherein either he or his forefathers were born. Here the rewards of his industry follow with equal steps the progress of his labour; his labour is founded on the basis of nature, self-interest; can it want a stronger allurement?8

Smith took for granted that people are driven by self-interest, by the desire to better their condition. “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner,” is how he put it, “but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves not to their humanity, but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.”9

Harnessed and channeled the right way, then, self-interest—when placed within certain rules and boundaries—can be good, leading to a more prosperous and humane society.

Morality and capitalism, like morality and democracy, are intimately connected and mutually complementary.

Here it is important to distinguish between self-interest and selfishness. Self-interest—unlike selfishness—will often lead one to commit acts of altruism; rightly understood, it knows that no man is an island, that we are part of a larger community, and that what is good for others is good for us. To put it another way: Pursuing our own good can advance the common good. Even more, advancing the common good can advance our own good, as every Christian knows full well.

Advocates of free enterprise believe that creativity, enterprise, and ingenuity are essential parts of human nature. Capitalism aims to take advantage of the self-interest of human nature, knowing that the collateral effects will be a more decent and benevolent society. Capitalists believe that liberty is an inherent good and should form the cornerstone not only of our political institutions but our economic ones as well. Free-market advocates also insist that wealth and prosperity can mitigate envy and resentment, which have acidic effects on human relations. Markets, precisely because they generate wealth, also end up distributing wealth.

The Relationship between Human Nature and Government

Why does all of this matter? Because our “picture of human nature” determines, in large measure, the institutions we design. For example, the architects of our government carefully studied history and every conceivable political arrangement that had been devised up to their time. In the course of their analysis, they made fundamental judgments about human nature and designed a constitutional form of government with it in mind.

What is true for creating political institutions is also true for economic ones. They, too, proceed from understanding human behavior.

Harnessed and channeled the right way, self-interest—when placed within certain rules and boundaries—can be good, leading to a more prosperous and humane society.

It is hard to overstate the importance of this matter. The model of human nature one embraces will guide and shape everything else, from the economic system one embraces (free-market capitalism versus socialism) to the political system one supports (democracy versus the “dictatorship of the proletariat”).10 Like a ship about to begin a long voyage, a navigational mistake at the outset can lead a crew to go badly astray, shipwreck, and run aground. To use another metaphor, this time from the world of medicine: A physician cannot treat an illness before diagnosing it correctly; diagnosing incorrectly can make things far worse than they might otherwise be.

Those who champion capitalism embrace a truth we see played out in almost every life on almost any given day: If you link reward to effort, you will get more effort. If you create incentives for a particular kind of behavior, you will see more of that behavior. The book of Thessalonians boils things down to fairly simple terms: “If any would not work, neither should he eat.”11

A free market can also better our moral condition—not dramatically and not always, but often enough. It places a premium on thrift, savings, and investment. And capitalism, when functioning properly, penalizes certain kinds of behavior—bribery, corruption, and lawlessness among them—because citizens in a free-market society have a huge stake in discouraging such behavior, which is a poison-tipped dagger aimed straight at the heart of prosperity.

The founders predicated that within every human heart, let alone among different individuals, strive competing and sometimes contradictory moral impulses and currents.

In addition, capitalism can act as a civilizing agent. The social critic Irving Kristol argued, correctly in our view, that the early architects of democratic capitalism believed commercial transactions “would themselves constantly refine and enlarge the individual’s sense of his own self-interest, so that in the end the kind of commercial society that was envisaged would be a relatively decent community.”12

But capitalism, like American democracy itself, is hardly perfect or sufficient by itself. It has a troubling history, as well as a glorious one. And, like America, it is an ongoing, never-ending experiment, neither self-sustaining nor self-executing. Capitalism requires strong, vital, non-economic and non-political institutions—including the family, churches and other places of worship, civic associations, and schools—to complement it. Such institutions are necessary to allow capitalism to advance human progress.

A capitalist society needs to produce an educated citizenry. It needs to be buttressed by people who possess and who teach others virtues such as sympathy, altruism, compassion, self-discipline, perseverance, and honesty. And it needs a polity that will abide by laws, contracts, and election results (regardless of their outcome). Without these virtues, venality can eat capitalism from within and use it for pernicious ends.

We need to understand that capitalism, like democracy, is part of an intricate social web. Capitalism both depends on this web and contributes mightily to it. Morality and capitalism, like morality and democracy, are intimately connected and mutually complementary.13 They reinforce one another; they need one another; and they are terribly diminished without one another. They are links in a golden chain.

Arthur C. Brooks is the president of the American Enterprise Institute. Peter Wehner is a senior fellow at the Ethics and Public Policy Center. This article was adapted from their newly published monograph, Wealth and Justice: The Morality of Democratic Capitalism.

FURTHER READING: Brooks recently discussed “Why Isn’t Spain Happy?” how “The Secret to Human Happiness Is Earned Success,” and “The New Culture War” concerning free enterprise.

Notes

1. Jean-Jacques Rousseau, The Social Contract and Other Later Political Writings, edited by Victor Gourevitch (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997).

2. Thomas Hobbes, Leviathan, ch. XIII, XVII (Forgotten Books, 2008), 86 (originally published in 1651).

3. Romans 6:13.

4. Alexander Hamilton, The Federalist, no. 15, par. 12, available here.

5. Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (Oxford University Press, 1976).

6. Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, book X, edited by Edwin Cannan (1904), available here.

7. Ibid., book IV, ch. II.

8. J. Hector St. John de Crevecoeur, Letters From an American Farmer, letter III, par. 8, available here.

9. Smith, Wealth of Nations, book I, ch. II.

10. Karl Marx, The Class Struggles in France, 1848 to 1850 (New York: International Publishers, 1965).

11. 2 Thessalonians 3:10.

12. Irving Kristol, Neo-Conservatism: The Autobiography of an Idea (Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 1999), 282.

13. “As there is a degree of depravity in mankind which requires a certain degree of circumspection and distrust,” Madison wrote in Federalist No. 55, “so there are other qualities in human nature, which justify a certain portion of esteem and confidence. Republican government presupposes the existence of these qualities in a higher degree than any other form.”

Image by Darren Wamboldt/Bergman Group.

 

Why Do the Poor Stay Poor?

By John Stossel

12/8/2010

Of the 6 billion people on Earth, 2 billion try to survive on a few dollars a day. They don't build businesses, or if they do, they don't expand them. Unlike people in the United States, Europe and Asian countries like Japan, South Korea, Hong Kong, etc., they don't lift themselves out of poverty. Why not? What's the difference between them and us? Hernando de Soto taught me that the biggest difference may be property rights.

I first met de Soto maybe 15 years ago. It was at one of those lunches where people sit around wondering how to end poverty. I go to these things because it bugs me that much of the world hasn't yet figured out what gave us Americans the power to prosper.

I go, but I'm skeptical. There sits de Soto, president of the Institute for Liberty and Democracy in Peru, and he starts pulling pictures out showing slum dwellings built on top of each other. I wondered what they meant.

As de Soto explained: "These pictures show that roughly 4 billion people in the world actually build their homes and own their businesses outside the legal system. ... Because of the lack of rule of law (and) the definition of who owns what, and because they don't have addresses, they can't get credit (for investment loans)."

They don't have addresses?

"To get an address, somebody's got to recognize that that's where you live. That means ... you've a got mailing address. ... When you make a deal with someone, you can be identified. But until property is defined by law, people can't ... specialize and create wealth. The day they get title (is) the day that the businesses in their homes, the sewing machines, the cotton gins, the car repair shop finally gets recognized. They can start expanding."

That's the road to prosperity. But first they need to be recognized by someone in local authority who says, "This is yours." They need the rule of law. But many places in the developing world barely have law. So enterprising people take a risk. They work a deal with the guy on the first floor, and they build their house on the second floor.

"Probably the guy on the first floor, who had the guts to squat and make a deal with somebody from government who decided to look the other way, has got an invisible property right. It's not very different from when you Americans started going west, (but) Americans at that time were absolutely conscious of what the rule of law was about," de Soto said.

Americans marked off property, courts recognized that property, and the people got deeds that meant everyone knew their property was theirs. They could then buy and sell and borrow against it as they saw fit.

This idea of a deed protecting property seems simple, but it's powerful. Commerce between total strangers wouldn't happen otherwise. It applies to more than just skyscrapers and factories. It applies to stock markets, which only work because of deed-like paperwork that we trust because we have the rule of law.

Is de Soto saying that if the developing world had the rule of law they could become as rich as we are?

"Oh, yes. Of course. But let me tell you, bringing in the rule of law is no easy thing."

De Soto started his work in Peru, as an economic adviser to the president, trying to establish property rights there. He was successful enough that leaders of 23 countries, including Russia, Libya, Egypt, Honduras and the Philippines, now pay him to teach them about property rights. Those leaders at least get that they're doing something wrong.

"They get it easier than a North American," he said, "because the people who brought the rule of law and property rights to the United States (lived) in the 18th and 19th centuries. They were your great-great-great-great-granddaddies."

De Soto says we've forgotten what made us prosperous. "But (leaders in the developing world) see that they're pot-poor relative to your wealth." They are beginning to grasp the importance of private property.

Let's hope we haven't forgotten what they are beginning to learn.

 

 

What's Wrong With Spain?

Its crisis is rooted in decisions to encourage regional divisions and to abandon successful market-based policies.

By JOSé MARIA AZNAR

Spain faces a critical economic situation. Along with Portugal, it is now at the center of Europe's financial turmoil. Investors are assigning higher default risks to the Spanish government's debt than at any point since Spain entered the euro zone.

In the social sphere, the situation is distressing. The unemployment rate exceeds 20%. The youth unemployment rate is above 43%.

It's not only the financial markets that are raising doubts about the Spanish economy. The European Commission has stated its worries about the current government's ability to react and implement credible economic measures to address the situation.

Wherever I go, people ask me the same questions: What's wrong with Spain? How is it possible that in just a few years my country went from being the "economic miracle" of Europe to the "economic problem" of Europe? What happened to the economy that just a few years ago grew more than 3% year after year, even when Germany, France and Italy posted zero growth? It is now the only economy out of Europe's five largest countries still experiencing negative growth.

All these questions bring me great sorrow and provoke a deep sense of concern for the present and future of my country. Just six years ago Spain was creating six out of 10 new euro-zone jobs, its government accounts were in surplus, its stock of public debt was decreasing swiftly, and its multinationals were expanding across Europe, Latin America and the United States.

My response to all the questions about Spain is clear: Spain is suffering the most serious political crisis of its recent history. The economic woes and the lack of confidence in Spain are the result of the government's credibility deficit. The high price being paid now by the Spanish people is what happens when politicians refuse to acknowledge their mistakes.

View Full Image

Bloomberg News

Six years ago, the country was creating six out of 10 new euro-zone jobs.

The roots of Spain's crisis lie in the political decisions made in 2004 to abandon the modernizing process that Spanish society began more than 30 years ago. At that time, Spaniards decided by consensus to consolidate our democracy and its institutions after nearly 40 years of dictatorship. The next step was to enter the European Union and later the euro, and converge economically and socially with the most thriving nations of Europe.

Then in 2004 Madrid changed direction. The government rejected the settlement embodied in the 1978 constitution and ruptured the makeup of the Spanish state. Different areas of the country were pitted against each other. The effect has been to erase much of what joins us as Spaniards and to turn Spain into a country that is very difficult to lead.

In the economic sphere, once Spain adopted the euro and currency devaluation ceased to be an option, the government abandoned its commitment to budget stability and the constant process of reforms necessary to remain competitive in global markets. These economic errors can be seen in the government's arbitrary interventions in business life, with flagrant contempt for the rules of the game—even the European rules. We also saw unprecedented growth of government spending and in tax hikes across the board.

Spain's current place in the international sphere reflects its declining weight in the world. The government has relinquished its responsibilities and has failed to defend its national interests abroad.

Only a new government can recover credibility, and that demands general elections.

A new government could call on the Spanish people to undertake a great national project for recovery, regeneration and reform of the nation. For this there are no miracles or shortcuts—there never were in the past and there won't be now. With a new national political project and the implementation of the appropriate policies, Spain can recover international confidence and credibility and Spanish people can recover confidence in themselves and in their nation.

An essential part of this political change will be for Spain to immediately acknowledge that the state has to limit its economic and social role, and open new areas of freedom and dynamism for society and private entrepreneurship. Spain needs to accomplish deep reforms in its administrative structure, including eradicating bureaucratic and public bodies and rationalizing public expenditure. Spain cannot delay any longer in reforming its welfare state, but must start now to restore the conditions for a thriving society that is open to all.

Spain is more than capable of becoming, once again, a dynamic and enterprising country, one that generates employment and opportunity. But first it must undertake the hard work of unwinding six years of political misdeeds. We can't We can't wait.

Mr. Aznar is the former prime minister of Spain (1996-2004).

 

 

Senior Fellow


Hi-Res Photo

Alvaro Vargas Llosa
Senior Fellow,
Center on Global Prosperity
Send Email

Alvaro Vargas Llosa is a Senior Fellow of The Center on Global Prosperity at the Independent Institute, a nationally syndicated columnist for the Washington Post Writers Group, and the author of the book Liberty for Latin America, which obtained the Sir Anthony Fisher International Memorial Award for its contribution to the cause of freedom in 2006. He was recently appointed Young Global Leader 2007 by the World Economic Forum in Davos.

Mr. Vargas Llosa is a native of Peru and received his B.S.C. in international history and an M. A. from the London School of Economics. He has been a member of Board of the Miami Herald Publishing Company and op-ed page editor and columnist at the Miami Herald, and a contributor to the Wall Street Journal, the New York Times, the Los Angeles Times, the BBC World Service, Time Magazine, Granta magazine, El País, the International Herald Tribune, and other media outlets. In addition, Mr. Vargas Llosa has been a commentator at Univision TV, news director at RCN radio, London Correspondent for Spain’s ABC daily newspaper, commentator at Radio Nacional de España in Madrid, host of the weekly TV program “Planeta 3” that aired in twelve Latin American countries for five years, and columnist at La Nación (Argentina), El Nacional (Venezuela), Reforma (Mexico), El Tiempo (Colombia), El País (Uruguay), El Listín Diario (Dominican Republic).

He is the author of the books The Che Guevara Myth, Liberty for Latin America, The Madness of Things Peruvian, Guide to the Perfect Latin American Idiot (with Carlos Alberto Montaner and Plinio Apuleyo Mendoza), El Exilio Indomable, Cuando Hablaba Dormido, El Diablo en Campaña, En el Reino del Espanto, Tiempos de Resistencia, and La Contenta Barbarie, and he is a contributing author to How I Learned English (edited by Tom Miller).

Mr. Vargas Llosa was the press spokesman for the presidential campaign of the Democratic Front in 1990 in his native Peru and an Advisor on International Relations for the presidential campaign of Perú Posible in 2001.

He is the recipient of the Sir Anthony Fisher International Memorial Award for his book Liberty for Latin America (2006), Juan Bautista Alberdi Award (2006) for his defense of freedom across the western hemisphere, the A.I.R. Award for Best Current Affairs Radio Show in Florida (1998), Puerto Rican Parliament’s Award for the Defense of Freedom (1997), Peruvian Association of Fishermen’s Award for the Defense of Freedom (2000), and Freedom of Expression Award given by the Association of Ibero-American Journalists (2003).

He has lectured widely on world economic and political issues. Among other venues, he has spoken at The World Economic Forum, U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Council on Foreign Affairs (U.S.), World Affairs Council (U.S.), Inter-American Dialogue (U.S.), Florida International University (U.S.), University of New York (U.S.), Cato Institute (U.S.), Atlas Economic Research Foundation (U.S.), Mount Pelerin Society (Chile), Naumann Foundation (Germany), FAES Foundation (Spain), Brazilian Institute of Business Studies, Fundación Libertad (Argentina), the CEDICE Foundation (Venezuela), Ecuatorian Chamber of Commerce (Ecuador), and University of San Marcos (Peru).

 

Books

Lessons from the Poor

2008

Making Poor Nations Rich

2007

The Che Guevara Myth

2006

Liberty for Latin America

2005

 

Events

Lessons from the Poor: The Power of Entrepreneurship

November 13, 2008

The Secret to Making Poor Nations Rich

February 21, 2008

Liberty For Latin America: How to Undo 500 Years of State Oppression

May 3, 2005

[View All Events (5)]

 

The Independent Review

The Individualist Legacy in Latin America

Winter 2004

Latin American Liberalism: A Mirage?

Winter 2002

 

Commentary

Latin America, 2011

December 29, 2010

Pakistan’s Crooked Roots

December 22, 2010

The Brighter Europe

December 15, 2010

Latin America: Wikileaks Relief

December 8, 2010

Bullying Ireland

December 1, 2010

[View All Commentary Articles (284)]

 

Presentations

The State of Freedom: 2006

April 21, 2006

The Freedom of Expression Award

December 12, 2003

 

Latin America: Pivotal Year Ahead

Latin America's middle class made visible gains in 2010, as economic growth outpaced that of the United States and Europe. But the region's underclass won't make significant gains unless governments adopt economic liberalization and meaningful political reform, according to Independent Institute Senior Fellow Alvaro Vargas Llosa. In fact, the fate of the poor over the next several years may depend on political developments of the next twelve months in Brazil, Peru, Argentina, and Venezuela.

Brazil's incoming president, Dilma Rousseff, will help set the tone by deciding whether or not to push for liberalization and to discontinue Brazil's anti-U.S. rhetoric. Peru's voters will decide whether to maintain the policies that helped bring about a mighty 8 percent growth rate last year--or whether to support foes of economic liberalization on the left or the right. Argentina's voters will decide whether to embrace the collective legacy of Nestor and Cristina Kirchner--or to adopt policies that would sustain the gains fostered by recent agricultural innovation and increased trade with Asia. And Venezuela's new National Assembly will decide whether to stand up to Hugo Chavez's intimidation and whom to select as an opposition candidate against Chavez's party.

"These political dynamics give Latin America a chance to make the modernization process irreversible," Vargas Llosa writes.

"Latin America, 2011," by Alvaro Vargas Llosa (12/29/10) Spanish Translation

Lessons from the Poor: The Triumph of the Entrepreneurial Spirit, edited by Alvaro Vargas Llosa

Liberty for Latin America: How to Undo Five Hundred Years of State Oppression, by Alvaro Vargas Llosa

The Che Guevara Myth and the Future of Liberty, by Alvaro Vargas Llosa

 

Dec 29, 2010
4:19 PM

Venezuela Inflation Highest Among Top Emerging Economies

By Kejal Vyas

CARACAS — Venezuela’s rate of inflation is the highest among the world’s top 42 emerging economies, according to a study by the Central University of Venezuela.

Estimated to have an inflation rate of 28% this year, the South American country is one of only five economies to have double-digit inflation, the study said. Pakistan, Egypt, India and Argentina were the other countries named facing high inflation.

The numbers underscore a major challenge for the administration of President Hugo Chavez as he looks to combat high inflation and a struggling economy.

Many Wall Street analysts expect Venezuela to be the only country in Latin America to experience an economic contraction this year, while the inflation rate has been projected as high as 35%. That is in stark contrast to neighboring countries such as Brazil, whose economy is seen expanding more than 7.5% in 2010.

In addition, the Venezuelan economy continues to struggle at a time when the price of oil, the nation’s main export, remains at a high and stable level.

This suggests that high oil prices are no longer a sufficient condition for the economy to regain its growth path,” said Jose Guerra, director of the economics department at Central University of Venezuela.

“High oil prices mean higher revenue but not increased economic activity,” he said in the report.

In addition, Guerra said that a political climate that is perceived as anti-business–the result of hundreds of expropriations this year–has also resulted in little investment into the country’s petroleum sector.

That has contributed to a decline in production by the country’s state-run oil giant Petroleos de Venezuela SA, or PDVSA, he added.

“If there is no change in policy, it’s probable that in 2011 high inflation and stagflation will persist,” Guerra said.

 

‘Trade Not Aid’ Not Enough for Africa

By Bob Davis

In a bid to boost economic growth in Africa, Congress passed the Africa Growth and Opportunities Act in 2000, which eliminated many tariffs and quotas for African goods. Imports of clothing from Africa boomed, particularly because Congress didn’t require — as it often does in trade deals — that exporters use fabric that is either made domestically or imported from the U.S.

 

Taiwanese and other Asian companies seized the opportunity to set up shop in the poorest African nations, import fabric from China, hire African sewing machine operators and ship the finished T-shirts and other goods to the U.S., duty free. So long as employment and development improved in Africa, the trade act was seen as a good deal, even if Asian companies benefited disproportionately.

Except it wasn’t such a great deal, according to a paper by economists Lawrence Edwards of the University of Cape Town and Robert Lawrence of Harvard University published by the National Bureau of Economic Research. While the trade deal did boost jobs for poor, landlocked Lesotho, for instance, it didn’t spur broader development. Ironically, the fabric provision — meant to give an extra boost to impoverished African nations — actually hindered them from building a domestic industry. Generosity backfired.

“The slogan of ‘trade not aid,’ can be misleading,” the economists conclude. “Trade preferences may help create the conditions for growth, but they are not sufficient.”

On the positive side, the trade deal provided about 50,000 jobs, mostly for Lesotho women. But the fabric provision meant that the largely Asian manufacturers imported relatively costly material from Asia and used Lesotho simply for cheap labor — and tariff-free entry into the U.S.

“In Lesotho, you make cotton T-shirts to sell in Neiman Marcus with expensive fabric and very little sewing, and on a huge scale,” said Mr. Lawrence in an interview.

That worked well until 2005 when a global quota system for textiles and apparel, called the Multi-Fiber Arrangements, expired. Largely freed of quota restrictions, Asian exporters expanded into lower-end fabrics in addition to the higher-end — and higher-profit — fabric they concentrated on when their exports were restricted by MFA quotas. Combined with low cost, highly productive workers, China and other Asian nations outmuscled Mauritius, South Africa, Mexico and many U.S. clothing makers for low-end goods.

Lesotho, which was still protected by tariff and quota preferences, held up better than other nations under the Chinese advance, the economists say, but the country didn’t advance. Lesotho’s GDP per-capita was $870 in 2000. While it improved a total of 50% over the decade, it’s still just $1,266 in 2010, according to the International Monetary Fund.

The continuing impoverishment is partly because fabric provisions didn’t encourage the development of a low-cost, domestic fabric industry that stood a chance of competing with Asia. So now, the economists say, the African apparel industry must rely on continued trade preferences to survive, while entrepreneurial China prospers without them

 

 

A Nation in Motion

The Census reveals a people who are moving to pro-market red states.

The Census is in. There are now 308.74 million Americans, an increase of 27 million, or 9.7%, since 2000. Americans are still multiplying, one of the best indicators that the country's prospects remain strong.

About 13 million of that increase were new immigrants. These newcomers brought energy, talent, entrepreneurial skills and a work ethic. Their continued arrival in such large numbers validates that the rest of the world continues to view the U.S. as a land of freedom and opportunity.

The Census figures also confirm that America is a nation in constant motion, with tens of millions hopping across state lines and changing residence since 2000. And more of them are moving into conservative, market-friendly red states than into progressive, public-sector heavy blue states.

In order the 10 states with the greatest population gains were Nevada, Arizona, Utah, Idaho, Texas, North Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Colorado and South Carolina. Their average population gain was 21%. In the fast-growing states, the average income tax rate is 4% versus 6.9% in the slowest growing states.

The average population gain of the bottom 10 states was 2%. They include most of the states now famous for fiscal distress: Michigan, Ohio, New York, Illinois. Michigan was the one state that actually had a net loss of population in the past decade.

Particularly troubling is that three of America's traditionally high-octane states—California, New Jersey and New York—are in the population and economic doldrums.

More

New York's population grew only 2%, while New Jersey grew at less than half the U.S. average. California's population, a source of its rising economic prosperity throughout the 20th century, grew only at the national average. For the first time since 1920, the not-so-Golden State failed to gain a single new House seat, an astonishing event. The place that once led the rest of the nation in technology, innovation, venture capital and cultural trend-setting is now reaping the whirlwind of its profligate political regime in Sacramento.

Meanwhile, the West and South continue to gain strength, while the Northeast, a blue state bastion, stagnates. Only New Hampshire, with the huge advantage of no income or sales tax, is doing relatively well, with population growth twice that of the rest of the region.

The Census exercise is also about the rise and fall of political clout, and here the runaway winner is Texas. It gets four new Congressional seats, followed by Florida with two seats, and Arizona, Georgia, Nevada, South Carolina, Utah and Washington gaining one seat. With the exception of Washington, these are all relatively Republican states.

The losers are states the Democrats traditionally look to for support. New York and Ohio lose two seats. Illinois, Iowa, Louisiana, Massachusetts, Michigan, Missouri, New Jersey and Pennsylvania are all down one seat. When combined with the impact of redistricting within states, Republicans could be in position to gain more House seats in 2012 on top of their 63-seat gain this year. You'd expect the blue states to undertake economic reform out of simple political self-interest.

The Census numbers are one way to judge which public policies are working in the country and which aren't. Texas is looking like the new California. And California, Michigan, New Jersey and New York need to look deep into themselves to discover a more promising result 10 years from now.

 

Japanese Farmers Sow Protectionism

Special interests that are even more entrenched than in other countries leave Japan falling behind Korea.

By RICHARD KATZ

News that a free-trade agreement (FTA) between the United States and South Korea is a big step closer to taking effect is causing consternation in Japan—and rightfully so. Korea has made FTAs with major trading partners a central plank of its economic strategy. In addition to the American pact, Seoul has also inked a deal with the European Union and five others, and is negotiating more. Japan, in contrast, is falling behind. The reasons for that warrant close study.

Japan does have 11 Economic Partnership Agreements, or EPAs, with the likes of the Association of South East Asian Nations and Mexico, and is negotiating with Peru and Australia. However, Japan's EPAs include countries that account for only 16% of its trade, compared to Korea's 36%. Tokyo has been consistently unable to reach pacts with big partners that are also farm exporters, like the U.S., EU and China. Moreover, Japan's deals tend to liberalize trade less than the high-quality FTAs Korea, the U.S. and EU strive to sign.

Agriculture is the most frequently cited obstacle. Such is the power of Japan's agricultural lobby that Japanese EPAs typically liberalize only about 50% to 60% of farm products aside from rice. Korea's FTAs with the U.S. and EU, by contrast, liberalize 99% of its non-rice trade.

But that raises the question: Why was Seoul able to overcome the determined opposition of its own farm lobby while Tokyo is not? In both countries, aging farmers toil on very small, inefficient plots. Korean farmers stand to lose more from freer agricultural trade than their Japanese peers. In Korea, the majority of farmers work full-time on their land and get most of their income from farming. In Japan, 80% of farmers are part-timers and farming provides only 15% of their incomes.

View Full Image

Getty Images

That flight to Narita doesn't have foreign produce in the hold, does it?

Nor are Japanese farmers much more successful in mobilizing public sympathy for their obstructionism. A recent poll by the Yomiuri newspaper found that 61% of respondents support the effort by Prime Minister Naoto Kan to join the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) trade negotiations even though any resulting deal would likely abolish all tariffs and quotas, including on farm goods. Asked in a 2010 Pew Research Center poll whether increased trade is a good thing, 72% of Japanese said yes, an overwhelming figure in light of Japan's reputation for deep-seated protectionism, even compared to the 88% of Koreans who agreed.

Rather, institutional arrangements help explain Japanese intransigence on trade. Compared to Korea, Japan's political system allows special interests such as farmers to exercise far too great a veto power over the majority.

One reason is simple electoral math: In Japan, a farmer's vote has more weight than a city dweller's. Roughly one-half of the people live in the six most urban prefectures, but they get only 38% of the district seats in the Upper House. The distortion in favor of rural districts is somewhat less in the Lower House, but it takes just one house to block a pact. In Korea, by contrast, the highly urban region around Seoul houses 48% of the voters and elects 45% of the seats in the unicameral parliament. In addition, in recent Japanese elections the rural vote has often been the swing factor between the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) and the Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ)

Japan's method for negotiating trade deals also provides ample opportunities for special-interest "tribes" within the Diet and ministries to influence trade talks. Each ministry negotiates the chapters of trade deals affecting sectors under its jurisdiction. So the Agriculture Ministry can veto an entire FTA or EPA by refusing to concede on farm issues.

In Korea, by contrast, the Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Trade is in charge of the entire negotiation, and is therefore able to make strategic tradeoffs between various sectors for the good of the economy as a whole. Moreover, unlike in Japan, Korean ministers and career officials see themselves not as independent actors, but as serving a strong president elected by popular vote.

Some Japanese politicians have attempted to address this impasse through the same kind of political bargain achieved in Korea: income support in exchange for trade liberalization. In Japan, as in Korea, subsidies already provide farmers with half their total income from farming activities (i.e., not counting income from other jobs). This compares to 23% in the EU, 10% in the U.S. and 2.7% in Australia. When he was DPJ leader, Ichiro Ozawa proposed that these subsidies be linked to trade liberalization. Nowadays, Foreign Minister Seiji Maehara explicitly points to Korea in proposing a similar bargain.

However, unlike their Korean counterparts, most Japanese politicians have been unwilling to force farmers to accept more liberal trade as the political cost for those subsidies. A case in point is Mr. Ozawa, who reversed himself and now supports the farm lobby in its effort to scuttle Japan's participation in TPP talks. The combination of subsidies and protection is costly for consumers, who pay 1.9 times the market price for food (compared to 1.7 times more in Korea, before it embarks on a major wave of trade liberalization).

Pro-trade politicians in Seoul have been able to build a political consensus for liberalization because trade is so manifestly vital to Korean prosperity. The ratio of trade to GDP was 107% in 2008, and Koreans know that they have to import in order to export—44% of the value of Korean exports consists of imported inputs, not just energy and raw materials, but also parts and capital goods. Hindering trade to protect farmers, who account for only 7% of employment and 2.7% of GDP, makes little sense to Korean voters.

Japan, in contrast, sees trade account for only 35% of its GDP while only 22% of the value of its exports consists of imports—and these are mostly energy and raw materials.

Unless Tokyo musters the political will to fix its electoral math and the veto power of individual ministries, the Japanese economy will continue to suffer. Money that goes to too-expensive food could be fueling other purchases; meanwhile, the farm lobby is blocking liberalization in other sectors that would spur greater exports, competition and prosperity.

Mr. Katz is the editor of the semi-weekly Oriental Economist Alert.

 

 

Mexican Demographics and the Coming Crisis

http://bigpeace.com/pmaffitt/2010/12/06/mexican-demographics-and-the-coming-crisis/

 

Posted by Peter C. Maffitt Dec 6th 2010 at 5:39 am in Economy, Foreign Policy | Comments (1)

What is not understood in Washington, and by most US citizens, is that Mexico, our closest neighbor, is our most important strategic foreign policy and economic trade nation. Mexican demographics both in Mexico and of Mexican-Americans in the US are key issues in understanding importance of Mexico.

In 1956 I attended a very memorable lunch in Mexico City during which the speaker extolled the current progress of Mexico. He referred to the 1910 Mexican Revolution, which this year is exactly 100 years ago, and the harsh decade after the Revolution. The statistics are not exact, but perhaps 5% to 10% of the Mexican population was killed, starved, or went in exile. In the 1930s the world wide Depression again was harsh on Mexico. But during the 1940s and the first part of the 1950s Mexico prospered. There was food for the population; there were vastly improved public health medical services; and the nutrition had improved greatly. With improved medical services the mortality rate had fallen dramatically. Poor peasant families were moving to the cities for vastly increased opportunities. Especially during WWII there were jobs and improving prosperity. Mexico in the mid 1950s was a proud, productive, growing nation.

Then the speaker began to talk about population. He expected the next census would have Mexico at a population around 40 million. Then he said the current birth rate was estimated to be 3.5%. That statistically meant Mexico could double its population every 20 years if Mexico maintained the 3.5% growth rate. He said in rough terms he expected Mexico in 1960 would have a 40 million population; then in 1980 Mexico would have 80 million; in 2000 it would be 160 million; in 2020 it would be 320 million; in 2040 it would be 640 million, and in 2060 it would be 1,280,000 billon. In other worlds with a straight line 3.5% growth rate in one century from 1960 Mexico would have over 1 billion population. That figure caught my attention and the attention of the entire audience-“espantoso”.

The next day I was told a copy of the speech was given to the President of Mexico.

When I got back to the States I discussed the talk with several friends. One friend who was an accountant replied “The Rule of Seven.” The Rule of Seven is a simple mathematical formula to determine how long it takes for a number to double over a period of years. For example with a population growth rate or interest rate of .035% divided into 7 would result in the number doubling in 20 years. In other words with a growth rate of 3% the population will double in 25 years; growth 2.5% the population will double 30 years; growth 2% the population will double in 35 years; and growth rate of 1% will double in 70 years. My friend noted that straight line projections never work as predicted.

Beginning in the 1960s Mexico had a very strong family planning policy. Today fifty years later Mexico has reduced its population growth rate substantially. Mexico in 2007 has a population estimated to be 106 million. The current estimates are Mexico has a birth growth rate of 1%, a miraculous birth rate reduction. One estimate is that in 2050 Mexico could have a population of 132 million.

The 3.5% population growth rate of the early 1950s has plummeted. But large numbers of Mexicans have moved to the cities. Today Mexico City is a megacity with millions and millions. Today there is an increasingly large elderly Mexican population with an increasingly smaller younger population to support the older generation. In contrast the Mexican American population in the US has maintained a high growth rate and have made major contributions to our nation.

The strategic problem will develop in the coming few years when Mexico changes from an oil exporting nation to an oil importing nation. The federal government of Mexico takes 91% of the national oil company PEMEX profits for 37%of the federal budget. When, not if, that income for the federal budget disappears there will continued upheaval. What needs to be watched is the Mexican economic growth rate, job formation, and GNP. Even more important we must continue to cooperate with Mexico to deal with the crime rate and the current destabilizing drug war drug wars.

In the coming federal election there is a probability the current PAN party will not regain the Presidency and the once long time PRI party will take power. The issue is will the coming economic storm, a totally predictable storm, create an increased migration to the US, in spite of increasingly restrictive US Immigration policies, in the short term or long term from a neighboring nation with over a 100 million population?

 

 

Why is New Zealand different (from Greece and Ireland)?

Tyler Cowen

It's not just the Kiwi fruit.  Via Eric Crampton, Matt Nolan informs us:

On the surface there appears to be a lot in common with the Irish, Greek, and NZ economies.  All three have high net foreign liability positions, liabilities are highly concentrated through banks who are borrowing overseas, all three have experienced some form of housing boom and lift in consumption, and finally all three appeared to have a relatively strong fiscal position before the GFC before moving into fiscal deficits after the shock.  And yet (so far) while the Irish and Greek economies and banking systems have collapsed, New Zealand’s has been fine.

There are two major differences that have helped reduce the implied risk on our debt, making New Zealand much less likely to experience a bank run:

  1. Our banking system is primarily foreign owned (Eric Crampton expands on why this is a good thing),
  2. We have a freely floating exchange rate – combined with having much of our debt denominated in NZ$ this is useful.

Addendum: Matt Yglesias offers relevant comment.

December 2, 2010 at 09:23 AM in Economics | Permalink | Comments (20)

 

 

'Contagion' and Other Euro Myths

Restructuring short-term debt as long-term debt—which is what default really means—would hardly be the end of the world.

By JOHN H. COCHRANE

Over the weekend, European finance ministers and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) announced a €90 billion fund to bail out Ireland. They also promised that no sovereign bondholder would lose a cent, at least through 2013. The amount of fuzzy thinking behind this decision is even bigger than the heap of euros now being shoveled upon Dublin.

The bailout is being justified on grounds of containing "contagion." This is nonsense. The notion is that news of an Irish restructuring would scare investors in Spanish bonds, who would start looking at Spain's ability to repay its debts and then demand higher interest rates.

But haven't investors in Spanish bonds already noticed that there's a bit of a problem? And wouldn't news of a giant bailout make these investors question Spanish finances as much as would news of debt restructuring?

Any contagion is entirely self-inflicted. The only way Ireland's fate affects Spanish investors is by changing the odds that the European Union (EU) will bail out Spain. And Spanish interest rates are rising, suggesting investors now think a Spanish bailout is less, not more, likely.

This is not, in fact, an Irish bailout. It's a bailout of the European (including British) banks that lent a lot of money to the Irish government and Irish banks. If European governments want to bail out their banks, let them do so directly and openly—not via the subterfuge of country bailouts. Then they should face the music: How is it that two years after the great financial crisis, European banks make so-called systemically dangerous sovereign bets, earn nice yields, and then get bailed out again and again?

View Full Image

 

Chad Crowe

 

European bank regulators should announce that sovereign debt is not risk-free, and that their banks need capital against sovereign loans, or they need to buy insurance (credit default swaps) against sovereign exposure. Will taking this step hurt bank profits? Well, yes. Sorry. That game, at taxpayer expense, is over.

At least the announcement of the bailout fund breathed the possibility that some debt-holders might have to take a haircut someday. But it will only be after 2013, and only then on a "case by case" basis.

The middle of the bailout road—where Europe now stands—is the worst place to be. An ironclad bailout guarantee can calm markets, if not taxpayers and currency holders. An ironclad no-bailout position works as well: Markets adjust, banks stop betting on sovereign debt, and regulators realize the risk and demand some capital or credit default swap coverage.

A vague, case-by-case threat is the worst combination. Assessing the value of bonds becomes a guess about the intentions of EU and IMF officials. The next crisis will be that much harder for the same officials, since so many big financial institutions will have bet on bailout and will be lobbying them hard.

The big culprit in all of this is short-term debt. There would be no crises if governments had issued long-term debt to match long-term plans to repay that debt. If investors become gloomy about long-term debt, bond prices go down temporarily—but that's it. A crisis happens when there is bad news and governments need to borrow new money to pay off old debts. Only in this way do guesses about a government's solvency many years in the future translate to a crisis today.

There are two lessons from this insight. First, given that the Europeans will not let governments default, they must insist on long-term financing of government debt. Debt and deficit limits will not be enough. Second, the way to handle a refinancing crisis is with a big forced swap of maturing short-term debt for long-term debt. This is what "default" or "restructuring" really means, and it is not the end of the world.

Governments like to roll over short-term debt for exactly the same reasons Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers did: It looks cheaper—at least until the crisis comes. But buying insurance is always expensive.

It's far less expensive than bailing out everyone, which is impossible. The party has to end somewhere. If not with Ireland, then with Spain. If not with Spain, then with Italy. If not Italy, then Germany. If not with Germany, then with printed euros and inflation.

Deep misunderstandings of the euro aren't helping. A currency union does not require a debt union. The major danger to the euro right now is that the European Central Bank is buying weak sovereign debt—not that Ireland or Spain might restructure. The euro as a currency is stronger if it is insulated from sovereign default.

We in the U.S. shouldn't indulge in schadenfreude. Bad ideas lead to bad decisions, and we are not lacking the former. Many U.S. states remain in deep trouble, and the federal government is still in a long-term fiscal pickle.

Our governments have also guaranteed trillions of dollars of debt—everything from mortgages and student loans, to say nothing of implicit guarantees to banks and state and local governments. These guarantees don't show up anywhere on the books, but investors could start adding them up very quickly. Remember that Ireland got into trouble by guaranteeing bank debt. U.S. government debt is also remarkably tilted to short maturities, with the majority being rolled over every year. The Federal Reserve's quantitative easing will tilt us further to shorter debt.

If, say, states start threatening default, will we act with any more wisdom? Not if we swallow the blarney coming out of Europe.

Mr. Cochrane is a professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business.

 

 

Thread:

Why isnt Mexico Rich?

Post:

Why isnt Mexico Rich?

Author:

Heather Hines

Posted Date:

November 14, 2010 10:43 PM

Status:

Published

In this freakonomics blog by Stephen Dubner the economy of Mexico is questioned. Dubner discusses how Mexico has agressively tried to reform their economic situation by opening to foreign trade and investment, achieving fiscal discipline, and privatizing state-owned enterprises; and still has failed to show development. Many prominent economist suggest that the combination of poorly functioning credit markets, distortions in the supply of non-traded inputs, and perverse incentives for informality are the reasons for lack of growth. One external factor is that Mexico exports a lot of goods that China sells rather than exporting goods that Chine sells. deeper investigation is going to have to happen for this question to be anwered but personally I believe and agree with the article that the growing drug trade based out of Mexico might be a desorted in Mexico's GDP figures.

http://freakonomics.blogs.nytimes.com/

 

January 24, 2011

http://www.ncpa.org/sub/dpd/index.php?Article_ID=20255&utm_source=newsletter&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=DPD

The Blue Food Revolution

Meat consumption is rising worldwide, but production involves vast amounts of energy, water and emissions.  At the same time, wild fisheries are declining, says Scientific American.

When modern coastal fish farming began about 30 years ago, virtually no one was doing things right, either for the environment or for the industry's long-term sustainability, says Scientific American.

Clearly, such ills were not good for business, and the industry has devised innovative solutions.  Kona Blue's strategy of situating the farm within rapid offshore currents is one example.  Other farmers are beginning to raise seaweed and filter-feeding animals such as mollusks near the fish pens to gobble up waste.  Throughout the industry, including freshwater pens, improvements in animal husbandry and feed formulations are reducing disease and helping fish grow faster, with less forage fish in their diets.

Source: Sarah Simpson, "The Blue Food Revolution," Scientific American, February 2011.

For text:

Scientific American February 2011 issue, pages 54-61

http://www.scientificamerican.com/article.cfm?id=the-blue-food-revolution (subscription required)

 

 

Schumpeter

Jan 20th 2011 | from PRINT EDITION  Economist

Firms from the developing world are rapidly catching up with their old-world competitors

 

IT IS remarkable how soon the idea that firms from emerging economies pose a serious threat to multinationals from the rich world has become old hat. “The novelty has become the norm,” concludes the latest annual report on these “new challengers” by the Boston Consulting Group (BCG). But familiarity does not make that threat any less real.

Five years ago, when BCG first reported on the rising stars of the developing world, the rich world was still reeling from the shock of the purchase of IBM’s personal-computing business by Lenovo, a Chinese company. That this acquisition proved something of a dud may comfort those in the old guard who suspect that the ambitions of these newcomers to enter the global stage exceed their ability to perform. Yet it has not diminished those ambitions. After a brief fall following the financial crisis of 2008, the number and size of cross-border acquisitions by the challengers rebounded strongly in 2010. In the past decade 60% of the foreign purchases by these developing-country multinationals have been of companies in the rich world; in the past two years the proportion was 70%.

In part, this may reflect the fact that the emerging economies recovered more quickly after the financial crisis, allowing their corporate champions to return more quickly to the acquisition trail. BCG has analysed 100 leading firms from emerging economies. The BRICs dominate: BCG looks at 13 companies from Brazil, six from Russia, 20 from India (six of which are part of the Tata empire) and 33 from China, with the rest spread widely. The list includes the world’s largest baker (Grupo Bimbo of Mexico), meat producer (JBS of Brazil) and aluminium manufacturer (United Company RUSAL of Russia), as well as the second- and fifth-biggest telecoms-equipment firms (Huawei Technologies and ZTE, both from China).

These 100 companies are looking lively. In the past decade they have seen their revenues grow by 18% a year on average, three times faster than non-financial firms in the S&P 500. And they have managed to expand fast without sacrificing profit margins, which at 18% were six percentage points higher than those of their (non-financial) peers in the S&P 500.

BCG argues that this is because they have managed to resolve three trade-offs that are usually associated with corporate growth: of volume against margin; rapid expansion against low leverage (debt); and growth against dividends. On average the challengers have increased their sales three times faster than their established global peers since 2005. Yet they have also reduced their debt-to-equity ratio by three percentage points and achieved a higher ratio of dividends to share price in every year but one. This is despite two significant exceptions: in pharmaceuticals, where the challengers have tended to make low-margin generic drugs; and in consumer goods, where they have focused on low-cost products, leaving the higher-margin niches to established global brands.

All this is impressive, but it seems implausible that these trade-offs have been “resolved”. More likely, they have been temporarily suspended during a period of unusually rapid growth. Indeed, having sprinted to catch up, the challengers may be about to discover that the real race has only just begun.

BCG identifies five trends that will determine how the tiger cubs fare against the old tortoises in the next few years. While China continues to spend heavily on infrastructure, its low-cost construction and heavy-equipment companies will surely prosper. They are not only building roads and bridges in China; one firm has won a contract to build a casino in America and more will doubtless follow. Likewise, with demand for scarce resources soaring, the miners and other commodity-based firms that have grown huge during the past few years—including several from Russia—may soon be positively elephantine.

The other three trends ought to worry the challengers a little. So far, a handful of emerging-market firms have defied the conventional wisdom that conglomerates are inherently inefficient. But will they continue to do so? As more and more of a conglomerate’s activities take place far from head office, inefficiencies will surely creep in. Still, old multinationals such as America’s GE insist that new technology and management techniques allow them to run sprawling operations efficiently. The challengers can surely use the same tools.

Tigers struggle to build brands

Building global consumer brands may prove tricky. So far, the tiger cubs have had more luck acquiring established brands (just as Lenovo bought IBM’s PCs, Grupo Bimbo bought Sara Lee’s North American bakery business) than persuading rich-country consumers to fill their baskets with the local favourites of Chinese or Egyptian shoppers. Whether such acquisitions make sense depends on the price.

Perhaps the most interesting trend is the challengers’ growing reliance on partnerships. More and more, they are hooking up not with established multinationals but with other emerging-market firms, to share knowledge, penetrate new markets and spread the risk of especially hair-curling investments. And when the challengers do join forces with well-known multinationals, they increasingly do so from a position of strength.

Yet for all that, many established multinationals believe they can hold their own. Several are learning from the emerging-market challengers how to be innovative and frugal at the same time. They may not be hiring at home, but many are expanding rapidly in the developing world. For instance, according to the Times of India, IBM is now the country’s second-largest private-sector employer. So don’t write off the old guard yet.


Economist.com/blogs/schumpeter

 

 

 

 

 

WSJ NOVEMBER 12, 2010

Ireland Isn't Greece

Dublin is paying for its blanket 2008 guarantee of all bank liabilities.

Hardly a day goes by without another piece of bad news coming out of Dublin. On Wednesday, 10-year government bond yields hit 8.6%, a record spread over German bonds. The cost of insuring against a default by the government has also soared to record levels, and the cost to Irish taxpayers of keeping the Irish banking system afloat keeps going up.

The latest round of recapitalizations, announced in September, drove Ireland's budget deficit to an astonishing 32% of GDP for the year, and nobody is convinced that's the end. Then, this week, European Commissioner Olli Rehn went to Dublin on a fact-finding mission and insisted that the Irish government had made "no request for assistance"—the same words we often heard before Greece was bailed out in the spring.

But Ireland is not Greece. Going into the 2008 financial panic, Greece had a sky-high debt burden, a stagnant economy and a serious structural deficit that the government had been hiding by fudging its statistics.

Ireland, by contrast, went into the crisis with a budget surplus, a debt-to-GDP ratio of some 27% and a strong record of recent growth that has left it one of the richest countries in the world. Ireland does have a serious problem with its banks, which are the source of its current and recent woes. A property boom and bust have left Ireland's biggest lenders with billions in bad loans on their books.

But more than the property mania and subsequent crash, what really distinguishes Ireland is the government's decision in September 2008 to guarantee all of the liabilities of the country's main lenders. This included not just depositors, but senior and subordinated debt holders as well. At the time, Finance Minister Brian Lenihan famously bragged that the blanket guarantee was "the cheapest bailout in the world." It is turning out to be one of the most expensive.

The government's guarantee rested on the idea that markets were merely "dislocated" and overreacting at the height of the panic: In other words, that the banks faced a temporary liquidity problem, not a threat to their solvency. The bad loans have since multiplied, and the government has been forced to inject ever more capital into the banks to keep all the creditors whole, at a cost to taxpayers that now exceeds €50 billion.

Still, Ireland's underlying fiscal position is not that bad. The government has some €20 billion in the bank (so to speak) and doesn't need to return to the debt markets until next year. It has already laid out a fiscal retrenchment of about €15 billion, or roughly 8% of GDP, over the next four years. And unlike Greece, it retains an attractive tax environment for business and the prospect of a return to growth that would help whittle down those deficits and debts. The worst thing that could happen to Ireland would be an IMF or EU-imposed austerity program that included a hike in the country's 12.5% corporate tax rate and other growth-killing measures.

The question remains whether the government in Dublin can overcome the sizeable obstacle of those open-ended commitments to make bank creditors whole. Mr. Lenihan has argued in the past that under Irish law depositors are not senior to senior bondholders, and so he's had no choice but to protect both. That seems a weak basis on which to mortgage the country for the benefit of bondholders.

Mr. Lenihan tore up the rules once to extend the guarantees. He could do so again to make clear who is, and isn't, made whole.

 

 

LBC Thursday, September 02, 2010

Can Chile Recapture'Golden Decade'?

       

[Font Size \/]

Can Chile recapture the growth of its 'golden decade'?

CHRONICLE SPECIAL
Knowledge@Wharton 

Chile’s economy appears to have held up well against significant recent headwinds, and some private-sector observers go so far as to suggest that growth rates similar to those of the "Golden Decade" may be realized again.

Despite the earthquake and subsequent tsunami in February, job losses and the closing of numerous small businesses last year because of the global financial crisis, Chile was the top destination for foreign direct investment in Latin America during the first quarter of 2010. During the recent World Conference for Trade and Development, the United Nations reported that Chile, with $5.7 billion in foreign direct investment, had outpaced Brazil ($5.6 billion) and Mexico ($4.3 billion) among favorite locations for investors in the first quarter.

What’s more, the Santiago Chamber of Commerce forecasts that Chile’s foreign capital flow this year could reach $15 billion to $20 billion. This is reflected in the dizzying pace in the service sector, communications, mining and retail sales resulting from higher spending on public and private reconstruction initiatives, and meaningful expansion in internal demand, according to a press note from the country’s Central Bank.

Analysts widely forecast that the Chilean economy could grow at a rate of 6 percent in 2010, which would be in line with the goal outlined by the government of President Sebastian Piñera. Chile’s economy contracted last year by 1.5 percent. But market optimism has run so deep that the private sector has voiced the possibility that Chile will return to annual growth of 7 percent, which it achieved from 1987 to 1997, a period known as the “Golden Decade.”

Things are different now, however, says Juan Eduardo Coeymans, a professor of macroeconomics at the Catholic University of Chile. During those golden years, Coeymans notes, a combination of unique factors accelerated growth. “Chile was emerging from a military dictatorship, and the arrival of democracy was strengthening economic deregulation and free trade,” he says. Those factors increased investor confidence and facilitated the arrival of significant volumes of foreign capital. They also encouraged a political climate of reform, leading to free-trade agreements with the world’s principal economies. None of these variables could recur with as much intensity, he says.

Chile has already taken maximum advantage of global trade liberalization. It has more than 20 free-trade agreements with countries including the United States, China, Japan and Australia, as well as with the trade blocs Mercosur (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay; Chile is an associate member) and the European Free Trade Association (Iceland, Lichtenstein, Norway and Switzerland).

UNRESOLVED ISSUES IN EDUCATION

Clearly, it is hard to replicate the economic globalization that played such an important role during the Golden Decade. Yet some argue that it is possible to re-create the climate of political consensus of those years to promote significant reform. Foremost should be reforms related to the quality of education, says Rodrigo Fuentes, professor of economic growth at the Institute of Economics at the Catholic University of Chile.

“You can’t aspire to an annual growth rate of 7 percent without accelerating productivity. In order to do that, you need to improve human capital, which also means incorporating initiatives for optimizing the level of education,” Fuentes says. Such reforms should involve training workers in the appropriate ways to adopt new technologies, to acquire more knowledge, and to become more professional in their respective areas, while strengthening their dependence on a base of formal education.

That is precisely the Achilles’ heel of the Chilean labor force, argues Andrea Repetto, professor of economics at the School of Government of Adolfo Ibáñez University. “The level of scholarship of our workers is low, as research projects have revealed.” According to CASEN 2006 -- the latest version of the main tool used by the government to evaluate educational policy -- almost 20 percent of the Chilean labor force have not completed eight years of primary education, while 40 percent have not finished secondary school. International achievement tests have ranked Chilean children below international standards over the last decade, Repetto notes.

This shows that Chile faces a tremendous challenge, Fuentes argues. Improving the quality of education takes time; results may be visible only over generations. Nevertheless, Fuentes says, productivity can be increased in a short period with changes in the labor market. Fuentes proposes making the workday more flexible; changing the system of unemployment insurance compensation; and devising more effective policies for adjusting minimum salaries so “any increases in salaries are reflected in an increase in real productivity.”

Repetto adds that it is important to deal with the labor market’s high turnover rate; some 35 percent of the country’s formal workers have work contracts that typically last only six months. Half of workers with indefinite contracts don’t last 12 months on the job, according to the Chilean government’s unemployment bureau. “As a result, it’s hard to train workers, and you spend a lot of money without changing the turnover rate,” Repetto says.

It will also be necessary, she notes, to promote telecommuting and labor incentives so companies can hire more women and young people.

THE HIGH COST OF ENERGY

Another important issue is the country’s dependence on high-cost energy, says Guillermo Le Fort, professor of economics at the University of Chile, in a report published by the Chilean economics magazine Capital. “If we don’t manage to significantly lower the high cost of energy by using all of our potential, it will be hard to recover our productivity.”

From 1995 to 2003, Chile maintained a competitive structure of energy costs, largely through imports of Argentine natural gas at a low price. In 2004, however, Argentina restricted its shipments of hydrocarbons, forcing Chile’s electric utilities to operate with imported diesel fuel, which made their costs shoot up.

Currently, two-thirds of Chile’s electric energy is generated with its own hydropower resources. But domestic production of petroleum, natural gas and coal are low, so Chile must import petroleum and liquid natural gas at high prices. Chile is counting on results from small renewable energy projects in the north and south, based largely on wind, the sun and biomass. However, “the cost of developing attractive energy alternatives continues to be very high,” says Hugh Rudnick, professor at the Institute of Electrical Engineering at the Catholic University of Chile.

What are Chile’s best options for lowering energy costs? Taking maximum advantage of hydroelectric resources and coal, Rudnick says. But Chile will have to wait until 2012 to exploit new hydropower complexes and coal-fired plants because construction of these projects has only recently begun.

Meanwhile, Chile can make progress in other areas. One is to improve government efficiency, Coeymans says. “There seems to be an enormous waste of resources in the government, when you discover that there are 70 journalists working inside the same ministry.” A recent Ministry of Health audit revealed that 160 lawyers and 70 journalists worked in the agency, provoking a public outcry. Fuentes says the government should correct these inefficiencies, which distort resource allocation and increase production costs.

COPPER AND LOW FISCAL DEFICIT

Despite these challenges, the consensus among experts is that various favorable factors will permit Chile to achieve high growth. One is the high price of copper on world markets.

Currently, the price of copper is above US$3.30 a pound on the London Metal Exchange. That, notes Coeymans, “is providing incentives for the big mining companies that operate in Chile to invest more capital in order to increase their production levels.” According to the Santiago Chamber of Commerce, mining was the leading sector for foreign direct investment in the first quarter, with $1.6 billion invested.

The world’s largest copper producer’s dependence on the extraction of the mineral “is a double-edged sword,” warns Javier Bronfman, professor of public policy at the School of Government at the Adolfo Ibáñez University. “It puts us in a delicate situation with regard to international fluctuations in that commodity.” When the global financial crisis broke out in September 2008, it struck a hard blow against copper prices, which dropped to US$1.14 a pound. That had a strong impact on production costs, which led to the closing of numerous small and midsize companies tied to the sector.

That is why Coeymans suggests that the government apply efficient mechanisms for covering price risks to protect not only small mining companies, but all smaller companies, “since they are responsible for generating more than 60 percent of jobs in Chile and contributing 30% of the GDP.”

But copper isn’t the whole story. Chile possesses strong macroeconomic accounts, which drive growth. “The best example is its extremely low fiscal deficit, which represents only 5 percent of its GDP, according to the latest report of the International Monetary Fund,” explains Dalibor Eterovic, professor of political economics at the School of Government of the Adolfo Ibáñez University. He is also manager of economic research and fixed income at LarrainVial, a Chilean provider of financial services.

In the context of the indebtedness affecting numerous developed countries, he says, “Chile offers the characteristics of a safe haven, which will make it easier for it to attract foreign capital.”

In any case, Chile’s future is in its own hands. Either it deals with the great unresolved issues and turns its economic advantages into high, sustained growth, or it lets these good times, which are more than satisfying to the country’s businessmen, become a lost opportunity.

Republished with permission from http://www.knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu -- the online research and business analysis journal of the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania.

 

 

  • SEPTEMBER 29, 2010, 10:45 A.M. ET

China's Next Leap Forward

The jump from middle-income to rich status is much harder to achieve than the ascent from poverty. But there are plenty of reasons to believe China's growth prospects remain strong.

By GARY S. BECKER

I just spent two weeks lecturing in China and Hong Kong, and discussing China's economic development with many economists, businessmen and government officials. China's progress since my first trip there in 1981 has been truly remarkable, and I expect considerable growth during the next decade. Nevertheless, China still faces many challenges if it is to move beyond middle-level income status into the exclusive club of high per capita income countries.

Related Video

No country in the modern world has managed persistent economic growth without considerable reliance on private enterprise and decentralized private markets. All centrally planned economies failed to achieve sustained development, including the Soviet Union before its collapse, China before market reforms began in the late 1970s, and Cuba since Castro's revolution in the late 1950s.

China's private sector has led its dominance in textiles, electronics, and other consumer and producer goods. It's followed the model of the "Asian Tigers"—Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan—and relied heavily on exports produced with cheap labor. In the process, China has accumulated enormous reserves, as Taiwan, Japan and other rapidly growing Asian economies did in past decades.

Poorer countries like China need not get everything "right" to grow rapidly through exports to richer countries. They need only have some strong sectors that use world markets to fuel overall growth. Japan's rapid growth from the 1960s-1980s was led by a highly efficient manufacturing sector. Yet at the same time Japan also had a large and inefficient service sector, and an agricultural sector that was riddled with subsidies and inefficient incentives.

Similarly, China's economy still has a glut of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) with excessive employment and low productivity. Their importance has fallen over time, but Chinese economists estimate that they still control about half of nonagricultural GDP. One crucial example is the state-controlled financial sector that makes cheap loans to other large, inefficient and unprofitable state enterprises. China's economy also suffers from extensive price controls, restrictions on migration, and many other structural barriers to efficient growth.

View Full Image

 

David Gothard

 

Some democracies, like postwar Japan, have made the economic reforms needed for sustained economic progress. India, for example, experienced rapid growth after it began in 1991 to shed a socialist orientation and encourage private investment and private initiative. But economic progress has been swift under autocratic rule as well, including in Chile under Augusto Pinochet, Singapore under Lee Kuan Yew, and Taiwan under Chang Kai-shek. Usually, however, personal freedom has grown along with rapid economic progress in autocratic governments. Chile, Taiwan and South Korea, for example, all became vibrant democracies after they'd grown rapidly for a number of years.

Something related has happened in China. The degree of personal freedom in China today is enormously greater than in 1981, when the vast majority of the population had essentially no personal freedoms. The Internet, in particular, has given hundreds of millions of Chinese access to all kinds of information, including what happens in democracies, and various criticisms of their government's policies. The government actively tries to censor the Internet, but these censors are easily bypassed. Students and others say they readily "climb the wall" by using cheap software (appropriately, made in America) that gives them direct access to the Internet in Hong Kong and hence avoids the censors.

I do not know how soon China will evolve into a political system with competing parties, or whether China will continue to have effective leadership under its single-party structure. But as the economy continues to develop it will be impossible to prevent personal freedoms from expanding, including the freedom to criticize economic and social policies.

Global markets allow poor countries to grow rapidly for a while, but it is far more difficult to grow beyond middle-income levels. Much has been made of the fact that a month ago China's aggregate GDP surpassed that of Japan. But all that means is China's per capita income is about 10% of Japan's, since China's population is about 10 times that of Japan. Despite its great economic advances, China still has a long way to go to become a rich country.

China's locally owned government enterprises have been more efficient than national enterprises. This is mainly because local government enterprises have to compete against each other, whereas national enterprises often receive monopoly positions. But competition among government enterprises is a partial substitute for competition among privately owned enterprises. If China wants to continue to grow rapidly it will have to reduce the scope of the SOEs, especially the national ones, and greatly expand the private sector in finance, telecommunications and many other fields.

Developing countries improve their technological base by importing technologies and knowledge developed in advanced countries. China has encouraged direct foreign investment in part to get access to the technologies of Japan, the U.S., Germany and other nations. Using technologies developed by others is still important after countries advance to middle-income levels, but these countries must then also develop more of their own technologies to advance much further.

To accomplish this transition, China has been promoting university enrollments and a growing R&D sector. University attendance in China has grown greatly since the late 1990s, propelled by rapid increases in the earnings of individuals with higher education. China is innovating more, but it is still a long way behind the U.S., Japan and other rich countries.

As for China's currency, it's true that the yuan is considerably undervalued due to Beijing's continued intervention in foreign-exchange markets. But the undervalued yuan is a gift to American and other consumers outside China because it makes goods produced in China much cheaper.

In effect, China sells goods cheaply to the rest of the world and receives in return U.S. and other paper assets that pay almost no interest, and will depreciate in value when inflation rates increase in the U.S. These are the main reasons why China should move toward floating the yuan.

Many Chinese officials believe that substantial yuan appreciation will make the SOEs even less competitive, thereby increasing unemployment and social unrest as these enterprises contract. Yet an undervalued currency not only leads to a further accumulation of paper assets but also weakens the incentives of Chinese companies to cater to domestic consumption—which is remarkably weak—and to upgrade their exports to higher quality products.

There is tremendous pride and enthusiasm among Chinese regarding their economic achievements, and a growing confidence that China is returning to its great-country status of centuries ago. This is reflected in the enormous energy of its professionals, entrepreneurs and workers. It is also reflected less attractively in the more aggressive stance of China toward Japan and other neighbors.

Yet with some enlightened leadership, along with greater faith in competition and private markets, China's prospects for continued growth—and for rapid improvements in the circumstances of the children and grandchildren of the present generation—are strong.

Mr. Becker, the 1992 Nobel economics laureate, is professor of economics at the University of Chicago and senior fellow at the Hoover Institution.

 

 

Guest post: only trade-fuelled growth can help the world’s poor

September 21, 2010 2:10 pm by beyondbrics

http://blogs.ft.com/beyond-brics/2010/09/21/guest-post-only-trade-fuelled-growth-can-help-the-worlds-poor/

0

By William Easterly

The Millennium Development Goals tragically misused the world’s goodwill to support failed official aid approaches to global poverty and gave virtually no support to proven approaches.

Economists such as Jeffrey Sachs might argue that the system can be improved by ditching bilateral aid and moving towards a “multi-donor” approach modelled on the Global Fund to Fight Aids, Tuberculosis and Malaria. But current experience and history both speak loudly that the only real engine of growth out of poverty is private business, and there is no evidence that aid fuels such growth.

Of the eight goals, only the eighth faintly recognises private investment, through its call for a “non-discriminatory trading system”. This anodyne language refers to the scandal of rich countries perpetuating barriers that favour a tiny number of their businesses at the expense of impoverished millions elsewhere. Yet the trade-related MDG received virtually no attention from the wider campaign, has seen no action, and even its failure has received virtually no attention in the current MDG summit hoopla.

This is all the more misguided because trade-fuelled growth not only decreases poverty, but also indirectly helps all the other MDGs. Yet in the US alone, the violations of the trade goal are legion. US consumers have long paid about twice the world price for sugar because of import quotas protecting about 9,000 domestic sugar producers. The European Union is similarly guilty.

Equally egregious subsidies are handed out to US cotton producers, which flood the world market, depressing export prices. These hit the lowest-cost cotton producers in the global economy, which also happen to be some of the poorest nations on earth: Mali, Burkina Faso and Chad.

According to an Oxfam study, eliminating US cotton subsidies would “improve the welfare of over one million West African households – 10 million people – by increasing their incomes from cotton by 8 to 20 per cent”.

Brahima Outtara, a small cotton farmer in Logokourani, Burkina Faso, described the status quo to the aid agency a few years ago: “Cotton prices are too low to keep our children in school, or to buy food and pay for health.”

To be fair, the US government has occasionally tried to promote trade with poor countries, such as under the African Growth and Opportunity Act, a bipartisan effort over the last three presidents to admit African exports duty free. Sadly, however, even this demonstrates the indifference of US trade policy towards the poor.

The biggest success story was textile exports from Madagascar to the US – but the US kicked Madagascar out of the AGOA at Christmas 2009. The excuse for this tragic debacle was that Madagascar was failing to make progress on democracy; an odd excuse given the continued AGOA eligibility of Cameroon, where the dictator Paul Biya has been in power for 28 violent years. Angola, Chad and even the Democratic Republic of the Congo are also still in. The Madagascan textile industry, meanwhile, has collapsed.

In spite of all this, the great advocacy campaign for the millennium goals still ignores private business growth from trade, with a few occasional exceptions such as Oxfam. The burst of advocacy in 2005 surrounding the Group of Eight summit and the Live 8 concerts scored a success on the G8 increasing aid, but nothing on trade.

The UN has continuously engaged US private business on virtually every poverty-reducing MDG except the one on trade that would reduce poverty-increasing subsidies to US private business. And while the UN will hold a “private sector forum” on September 22 as part of the MDG summit, the website for this forum makes no mention of rich country trade protection.

The US government, for its part, announced recently its “strategy to meet the millennium development goals”. The proportion of this report devoted to the US government’s own subsidies, quotas and tariffs affecting the poor is: zero. News coverage reflects all this – using Google News to search among thousands of articles on the millennium goals over the past week, the number that mention, say, “cotton subsidies” or “sugar quotas” is so far: zero.

It is already clear that the goals will not be met by their target date of 2015. One can already predict that the ruckus accompanying this failure will be loud about aid, but mostly silent about trade. It will also be loud about the failure of state actions to promote development, but mostly silent about the lost opportunities to allow poor countries’ efficient private business people to lift themselves out of poverty.

William Easterly is professor of economics at New York University and co-director of its Development Research Institute

 

 

Venezuela on the Brink

http://www.commentarymagazine.com/viewarticle.cfm/venezuela-on-the-brink-15528
James K. Glassman

WEB ONLY

E-mail This Article to a Friend

Subject: Venezuela on the Brink 

[ ]

Yes, I would like to receive periodic updates and information via e-mail from Commentary.

Recipient Addresses:

Separate each address with a comma.

Your E-mail Address:  [          ] Message:  

E-mail This Article to a Friend

Thank You

A link to

"Venezuela on the Brink"

has been emailed to your friends.

Most E-mailed articles:

Venezuela goes to the polls on Sept. 26 in a parliamentary election that opponents of President Hugo Chavez see as “a chance to turn the tide,” as Reuters news service puts it. Chavez may be taking on more authoritarian powers, but he also has to defend what the latest data show is the worst economy in the world. And you thought the Democrats had problems!

The Economist magazine provides statistics weekly on 57 nations, from the United States to Estonia. Its most recent report forecasts that gross domestic product in Venezuela will decline by 5.5 percent in 2010. Next worst is Greece, with a 3.9 percent decline. Greece, of course, came close to defaulting on its debt earlier this year, and analysts at Morgan Stanley worry that Venezuela is moving in the same direction.

“Our new baseline of at least three years of economic contraction suggests the risks to Venezuela’s ability to honor its international financial commitments may be on the rise,” wrote Daniel Volberg and Giuliana Pardelli in a June report, at the same time predicting that GDP will fall by 6.2 percent in 2010. “While most of Latin America, in line with the globe, has been in recovery mode since last year, Venezuela has seen an intensifying downturn in activity,” they added.

So that’s GDP, the single best measure of economic health. When it comes to inflation, no one is close to Venezuela. Consumer prices are already up 31 percent for 2010 and are expected to rise more by year-end. Only two of the remaining 56 nations monitored by the Economist are suffering double-digit inflation: India and Egypt, both with 11 percent price increases.

Venezuela’s stagflation is all the more remarkable because, as the No. 8 oil-producing nation in the world, the country should be benefiting handsomely from high oil prices.

These results, however, should come as no surprise. Venezuela is suffering from serious economic mismanagement as the central government takes control of more and more sectors. Over the last three years, Chavez has nationalized firms in such industries as cement, steel, agribusiness, banking, tourism, oil, communications, and electricity.

Chavez has another problem: violent crime. Caracas, the capital, has nine times the homicides per 100,000 people as Bogota and 15 times the rate of Sao Paulo. Overall, according to Newsweek, Venezuela has “the worst murder rate in the hemisphere,” and it has helped push “President Chávez’s approval ratings off a cliff.”

Indeed. In a survey last month, Consultores 21 found that only 36 percent of Venezuelans approved of Chavez’s performance, a seven-year low.

Chavez has responded to these ills by shutting down media outlets, restricting economic freedom, blaming his critics, and throwing political opponents and businessmen in jail.

In March, he imprisoned Oswaldo Alvarez Paz, after the former state governor said on Globovision TV, “The Venezuelan regime has relations with structures that serve narco-trafficking, like the FARC [the Colombian terror group] and others which exist in the continent and the world.” In May, a retired general, Raul Isaias Baduel, once Chavez’s defense minister but now a critic, was sentenced to a prison term of nearly eight years on charges of misappropriation of funds. Those two join what Reuters calls “a list of several dozen Chavez opponents now in jail, living in exile or facing probes.”

Earlier this summer, the government issued an arrest warrant for Guillermo Zuloaga, the principal owner of Globovision, which the New Republic, in a blistering editorial about Chavez, called “the country’s last remaining major TV station with sympathy for the opposition.”

The pattern is clear: like Gen. Baduel, the charges against Zuloaga were economic -- in this case, that he “hoarded” automobiles on his property, a strange claim that had been made against him before and shelved. Zuloaga was to be held in one of the most notorious prisons in Latin America, but he fled the country and is now in exile.

In an interview in July with Mary O’Grady of the Wall Street Journal, Zuloaga said the arrest warrant came because his TV station has been reporting the dire conditions in Venezuela today. "The quality of Venezuelan life is deteriorating considerably, at the same time one of the biggest corruption scandals has come out with 70,000 tons of food rotting in the ports,” he said. “We have problems with electricity, problems with water, the highest crime rate of any place. … The Chávez government has infringed almost every article of the constitution."

At the time of Zuloaga’s arrest, the government also seized control of Banco Federal, claiming that the bank was not meeting liquidity requirements. Nelson Mezerhane, the bank’s president, is a major investor in Globovision, and the Wall Street Journal reported that the connection with Zuloaga was “the actual reason the bank was seized.” Mezerhane has also fled the country.

Unlike Zuloaga and Mezerhane, another prominent businessman, Ricardo Fernandez Barrueco, a billionaire banker and food supplier, is languishing in jail. Barrueco’s case was likened in an article on Forbes.com to that of Mikhail Khodorkovsky, the former CEO of the energy giant Yukos and a critic of former Russian President Vladimir Putin. Barrueco was first imprisoned in November and not charged with alleged banking violations until July. Barrueco’s assets, ranging from tuna boats to trucking fleets to shares in such companies as flour maker Molinos Nacionales, have been seized by the government.

Also targeted by Chavez is another food-production executive, Lorenzo Mendoza. A Miami Herald article in July reported that “Chávez is gunning for Empresas Polar, the country's giant food and beer conglomerate. The company, owned by the Mendoza family, is an obstacle to the government's plans for state control of the food industry.”

Once again, Chavez is accusing someone of “hoarding” -- in the case of Mendoza, it’s food rather than cars. The Herald article quotes an expert, however, as saying that the government has already mismanaged the part of the food-production sector it already controls. If Empresas Polar is taken over, says Carlos Machado Allison of the IESA business school in Caracas, “there would be terrible unemployment and many producers would have nowhere to place their products.''

In an attempt to prevent Venezuelans from learning what is happening in their country, Chavez has been dismantling independent media. In 2007, RCTV, the popular over-the-air television station launched more than 50 years ago, lost its broadcast license for criticism of Chavez. RCTV then moved to cable, where it became the most popular network but soon ran afoul of Chavez again. Dozens more stations have been shuttered. Chavez’s latest move, in June, was the creation of what Human Rights Watch calls an all-powerful “censorship office.”

Last month, a photo on the front page of the newspaper El Nacional showed more than a dozen corpses of homicide victims in the morgue. It caused outrage at the government, which responded by ordering the paper to stop publishing any images of violence, “as if that would quiet growing questions about why the government -- despite proclaiming a revolution that heralds socialist values -- has been unable to close the dangerous gap between rich and poor and make the country’s streets safer,” wrote reporter Simon Romero in an article in the New York Times.

But even a news blackout would not prevent Venezuelans from knowing firsthand what is happening to their nation’s economy. Retail sales were down 12 percent in the first half of the year; sales of food, beverages, and tobacco in specialty stores were off 30 percent. Chavez slapped on permanent exchange controls to prevent “the oligarchy from taking U.S. dollars and depositing them in banks around the world.” But like most such controls, they have only panicked investors and businesses and led to more capital flight. Figures from the Central Bank of Venezuela showed $9 billion in capital outflows in the first half of the year.

As they go to the polls this month, Venezuelans will undoubtedly be concluding that arrests, censorship, and other restrictions on liberty are no substitute for economic and political freedom and sensible public policy.

 

Cutting the corruption tax

Paul Romer
11 August 2010

Print   Email
Comment   Republish

 

For many, corruption and political cronyism are seen as an inevitable part of Greek politics. This column argues that the same could have been said in the 1970s about Hong Kong, now a beacon of low corruption. Hong Kong managed this turnaround by appointing a non-elected governor accountable to the UK government. Greece could achieve the same by calling on the EU and start counting the benefits.

 

Many of us take it for granted that government officials will obey the law. In the US, news that the police department in New Orleans committed and covered up crimes like rape and murder reminds us that this needn’t be the case. It also reminds us that living with the lawlessness of a weak state might be better than living under a strong state that officials can abuse.

Many nations live with a weak government because people fear that a strong govern¬ment will abuse its power. This fear is particularly acute in a country like Greece, where people can still remember the time in the late 1960s when military officers seized control of the state and brutally sup¬pressed dissent.

Unfortunately, the current economic crisis in Greece is too serious for its weak state to man¬age. In New Orleans, the mayor and community leaders asked the federal Department of Justice to intervene and reform the city’s dysfunctional police department (Robertson 2010). Like the city government in New Orleans, Greece needs to reach out for help.

An achingly slow recovery from the financial crisis could threaten the foundations of Greek society. To avoid this, the people of Greece should reach out to the EU – not for more loans or for budget supervision but for assurance that new efforts to root out corruption and civil service inefficiency will be politically neutral. By working with the EU, Greece can quickly build the kind of strong, honest, and efficient state that can lead the country out of the crisis.

The situation in Greece

Corruption and bureaucratic inefficiency amount to a tax on all firms that operate in Greece’s formal sector. The tax is especially onerous for start-ups and foreign firms that would like to invest there.

Here’s how one business leader, call him John, described a recent encounter with a local official. The official withdrew the license of one of John’s operations. It would be reinstated only if John agreed to hire the official’s girlfriend as a consultant and pay her via an offshore account. John’s legal recourse was limited – any case against the official would linger in the courts indefinitely. In the meantime, John’s firm would not be able to operate without the license. John ended up speaking to someone higher in the government to get the local official to back down. He did not say what the higher-level official got in return.

This kind of behaviour is no secret. In Transparency International’s 2009 corruption rankings, Greece tied Romania and Bulgaria for the worst score in the EU. At this level, corruption has visible effects on the overall efficiency of government. Daniel Kaufmann (2010) points to a strong correlation between cor¬ruption and fiscal deficits, even in industrialised countries like Greece. The budget position in Greece suffers from tax evasion and the political patronage that bloats public payrolls with un¬necessary hires. Kaufman suggests that if Greece’s levels of corruption were comparable to Spain (hardly the gold standard), its budget shortfalls over the preceding five years would have averaged as little as 2.5% of GDP rather than the current 6.5%.

As Marcus Walker points out in the Wall Street Journal, roughly one-quarter of all taxes owed in Greece are not paid. Walker also notes Prime Minister George Papandreou’s frustration with the many Greek politicians who promise public administration jobs to constituents to secure votes. The finance ministry estimates that the government added 27,000 people to its payrolls in the run up to the fall 2009 election, even though many of the new hires lacked an official position and an office (Walker 2010).

The costs of patronage go far beyond the salaries for unneeded civil servants. In a work environment where political patronage trumps merit, employee discipline is slack, government agencies are poorly run, and graft is widespread. One particularly important failure lies in the judicial system, which is notoriously slow at resolving cases. As the local official who demanded the payments to his girlfriend understood, this dramatically broadens the opportunities for criminal activity.

The business official who spoke to me earns a living by collecting part of the corruption tax. Foreign firms invest in Greece through his companies while he manages the demands from the officials. But his efforts come at a cost. Using data from global firm-level surveys, Kaufmann and Wei (1999) find that the managers of firms that pay more in bribes are likely to spend more time, rather than less, quibbling over red tape with bureaucrats than firms that refuse to pay bribes. They also find that bribers have a higher cost of capital.

The benefits from eliminating the corruption tax

Corruption and bureaucratic inefficiency act like the worst kind of tax – one that deters economy activity without raising any revenue. In the midst of the current crisis, cutting this tax would be a triple-win. In the long run, it will raise potential output. In the medium run, it will narrow the current-account deficit by reducing the cost of producing goods in Greece. In the short run, it will encourage investment by foreign firms and start-ups, which will bring the economy back toward full employment.

The existing approach, based on fiscal tightening, can reduce the budget deficit and, by temporarily reducing imports, help balance the current account. Some commentators suggest that a longer recession may be an unwanted side effect. In fact, prolonged recession is an essential part of this approach to reducing the current-account deficit. If Greece relies solely on fiscal tightening, a long and deep recession will be the only way to drive wages low enough to permanently change the costs of production in Greece relative to its trading partners.

To avoid the need for a long recession, many countries enact adjustment programmes that combine fiscal austerity with a cut in the exchange rate. Because it is part of the Eurozone, Greece does not have this option. In this context, the tax from corruption and inefficiency is an opportune obstacle – by removing it Greece can cut costs and become a more competitive place to do business. We don’t know the exact magnitude, but this tax cut might be large. A young person who is trying to grow a new business told me he would happily pay a 15% increase in the VAT if he could deal with a government that was as honest and efficient as the government in Hong Kong.

The experience in Hong Kong

Until recently, Greece had five layers of government instead of the three levels – local, state, and national – that are standard elsewhere. The extra levels of government increase opportunities for corruption and inefficiency, so the current administration has wisely chosen to consolidate. But even with fewer levels of government, corruption and inefficiency will linger in those that remain.

Some say that corruption and political cronyism are an inevitable part of “the Greek reality”. As long as there is government in Greece, there will be a tax from corruption and inefficiency. In the 1970s, the same sorts of cultural pessimists thought that Hong Kong would always be corrupt. The actual experience there demonstrates just how wrong they were. Feasible policies can quickly change a culture of corruption.

As in many places, the responsibility for fighting official corruption in Hong Kong once rested with a special branch within the police force that was conveniently ineffective. In 1974, the governor general of Hong Kong vested anti-corruption responsibilities in a new elite ministry, the Independent Commission Against Corruption (ICAC). The commission was directly responsible to the governor general, who was himself an appointed rather than an elected official.

The governor general in Hong Kong was not an authoritarian leader. He answered to the democratically elected British prime minister but his position did not depend on local political contests. As a result, neither the governor general nor the commissioners that answered to him had any interest in using the substantial powers of the commission for narrow political gain. They could be trusted with strong powers because they were held accountable to an offshore democracy that wanted Hong Kong to thrive.

Unsurprisingly, the ICAC’s efforts met with considerable resistance from the police. The governor general was eventually forced to grant amnesty for past crimes after the police went on strike and threatened violence. Though amnesty was viewed as a setback at the time, it meant that the commission could use all of its resources to prosecute fresh cases involving corrupt police officers and officials. This made it a much better deterrent against continued corruption.

Along with the formal prosecutions, the ICAC used education to change Hong Kong’s social norms regarding corruption. It organised a broad campaign, adding anti-corruption classes to the public school curriculum and creating anti-corruption television programmes. It published surveys that tracked changes in the amount of corruption over time. The commission also reviewed the rules of all ministries and modified them to reduce opportunities for corruption (Manion 2004).

So much for Hong Kong’s intractable culture of corruption. According to the surveys, the frequency of requests for bribes fell very quickly. Today Hong Kong is among the least corrupt places in the world, ahead of Japan, the UK, and the US.

Guns at a fistfight?

If a commission like the one in Hong Kong could eliminate the corruption tax in Greece, and if doing that would be so beneficial in the midst of the current crisis, why hasn’t one been established there? The problem is as old as Greek democracy. As Plato observed, if guardians are how we prevent lawlessness, who guards the guardians?

Government agencies that are strong enough to prosecute corruption cases and root out inefficiency in the civil service will also be susceptible to abuse. Selective prosecution and civil service dismissals could easily be used to help one political party and hurt another. Even if these powers are used in a neutral way, those who are caught will claim that the motivation for their prosecution was political. Unless such repeated assertions can be decisively rebutted, they could undermine the commission’s legitimacy.

Political competition in Greece is like a fistfight in a bar. Creating a powerful new commission would be like tossing a gun into the middle of the brawl. All parties remember how strong state powers were abused during the military takeover. Left on their own, they might reasonably agree that new powers would be destabilising and dangerous. But given the chance, they might still want to invite a new sheriff to town.

Bringing in the EU

Because of its membership in the EU, Greece has an option that is not available to most other countries in the world. By leveraging the credibility of the EU, Greece can begin the same sort of transformative fight against corruption that Hong Kong embarked on in the 1970s. If the EU can ensure that the appointment process to an anti-corruption commission is free of political influence, Greeks could remove the corruption tax without disrupting the political equilibrium.

The process could be structured in many different ways. For example, Greek political parties and members of civil society could propose names for head anti-corruption commissioner. The president of the EU could then make an appointment from the list, retaining the power to remove, replace, or reappoint the commissioner. Like a central banker, the head commissioner could have a clear mandate and wide discretion for achieving it, particularly in hiring and firing commission staff. The mandate could focus on the future, following the example of Hong Kong and specifying amnesty for past corruption.

The involvement of the EU could expire with a sunset clause. The clause might be based on a supra-majority vote in a referendum. The clause could also be triggered by objective indicators of performance, such as Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index or the World Bank’s Control of Corruption measure.

A similarly independent commission could bring the most basic elements of management to the Greek civil service. A civil service commission could end the practice of hiring and promotion based on political patronage. People who do their jobs would be rewarded. People who don’t would be advised to change, counselled out, or fired. With this kind of approach, essential government organisations like the courts and tax agencies could actually perform their functions.

What’s at stake

The fate of the entire EU project – to improve all aspects of governance in its member states – hinges now on how the crisis in Greece is resolved.

Proposals for centralised oversight of EU member-state budgets are both too hard to implement and too narrow in their focus. The proposals outlined here, independent commissions that promote honesty and efficiency in government, could be implemented quickly and would be far more helpful. They can be prototyped in a way that is specific to the situation in Greece, then adapted to other countries as necessary.

Many well-established democracies in the EU have solved the problem of guarding strong guardians. Through the institutions of the EU, they can assist people who still live without the remarkable benefits that this can offer, just as the federal government in the US can assist the people of New Orleans. In Greece, as in New Orleans, all it would take is for the local government to ask.

References

Kaufmann, Daniel (2010), “Can Corruption Adversely Affect Public Finances in Industrialized Countries?”, Brookings Institution.
Kaufmann, Daniel and Shang-Jin Wei (1999), “Does Grease Money Speed Up the Wheels of Commerce?,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2254.
Manion, Melanie (2004), Corruption by Design, Harvard University Press.
Robertson, Campbell (2010), “Justice Department to Review New Orleans’s Troubled Police Force”, The New York Times, 17 May.
Walker, Marcus (2010), “Tragic Flaw: Graft Feeds Greek Crisis”, Wall Street Journal, 15 April.
 


This article may be reproduced with appropriate attribution. See Copyright (below).

 

The Role of Culture in Economic Development

 

 

Francis X. Hezel, SJ

Micronesian Counselor #77 (June 2009)
Adobe Acrobat PDF here

 


http://www.micsem.org/pubs/counselor/frames/culture_economic_developmentfr.htm

How Flat is the World?

"The world is flat," Thomas Friedman has famously declared. His claim is that in this modern age of globalization, when capital can cross national borders so easily, when investment funds can be pulled from one country to another instantaneously to respond to new business opportunities, economic development is attainable in the most surprising of places. Today, as never before in the past, economic growth should be within the reach of any country anywhere in the globe.

All that is required for the golden fruit to flower, it would seem, is to have the door open to investment and the phone at hand. Naturally, there are conditions to be met to attract investment dollars (or yuan or yen or Euros or pesos). But given a stable government, the assurance that the rule of law will be upheld, and an investor-friendly climate, any country should be a position to become the new Singapore-a nation powered by steady economic growth.

The hitch is that not all needy nations are able to meet these conditions. In some parts of the world, in fact, almost none are--as if some toxic substance in the soil makes it impossible for economies to take root there. But even if most of the primary conditions are met-in other words, the government is responsible and the country has the official welcome mat out for foreign businessmen-there may other factors that make investors shake their heads and walk off with the decision to drop their money somewhere else. Perhaps the world isn't flat, after all. Possibly there are ingredients for economic development, more far-reaching and subtler than the conditions usually prescribed, that touch on the national ethos and its traditions. In other words, economic development might well be affected by those intangibles that are collectively known as culture.

Flirtation of Economics with Culture

Economics, once known as "the dismal science," has come a long way since its early days. The discipline, relying on its scientific formulas and precise metrics, has patented a storehouse of remedies for ailing economies. Yet it doesn't seem to know what to do with a concept as untidy as culture.

It wasn't always this way, though. Back in its earliest days, economics had plenty of room for the vagaries of human behavior. Adam Smith, sometimes regarded as the founder of modern economics, argued in his classic work Wealth of the Nations (written in 1776) that each individual, motivated by the pursuit of his own interests, contributes to the public interest in a system that is self-regulating. Smith was keen-sighted enough to recognize that the "pursuit of personal interests" involved much more than just making money. Hence, his tract, "Theory of Moral Sentiments", deals with what today we would call cultural values. John Stuart Mill, writing 70 years later, made the same point when he noted that cultural constraints on individuals could have a stronger impact on them than the pursuit of personal financial gain.

Max Weber, the German social scientist writing in the early 20th century, offered more specific insights into how cultural or even religious values could impact on economic output. He argued that the Protestant work ethic, supported by Reformation teachings that the pursuit of wealth was a duty, inculcated the virtues needed for maximum economic productivity. For this reason, Protestants were more productive than Catholics throughout Europe-just think of Germany and Great Britain, for instance, compared to Ireland, Spain, Portugal and Italy in his day.

In the meantime, the worldview of economists was radically changing. Economic progress was now a given, as the discipline shed its grim premise, first enunciated by Thomas Malthus in the 18th century, that population growth doomed people to a declining standard of living. Malthus believed that total wealth was a constant-there was only so much land and a strict limit to the resources it could produce, after all-and that most of the world's population would inevitably be reduced to fighting over the scraps from the table. The remarkable growth in the economies of the United States and many European countries during the 19th century, however, provided evidence that a different set of assumptions was needed. Economic theory was subsequently guided by a new insight: there was not simply a fixed amount of wealth, but an ever expanding economic pool to draw from. This meant, for one thing, that those nations that had little industrialization and whose people lived a largely subsistence life could join the more highly developed nations at the table. In theory, there would be plenty for everyone to eat.

After having offered hope to the underdeveloped that they could join the party, economics seems to have narrowed its field of vision since the 1930s and dedicated its energies largely to generating ever more sophisticated formulas relating to such things as markets, rents, income policies, price stability, and inflation control. It has also been busy refining its set of mathematical tools to test the theories that the discipline has been generating. Its principal interest has been in measuring the impact of different strategies on financial and economic crises so as to develop a dependable set of guidelines for predicting and managing these crises.

But as it has been doing all this, it appears that its interest in culture has been waning. Its presupposition seems to be that Homo economicus, no matter where he happens to be dwelling, is subject to the same ineluctable laws of supply and demand, maximization of profit, and pricing. The apparatus it's devised to analyze and manage economic situations are self-contained and have little room for the vagaries of human behavior. Today, ironically enough, with the prophets of globalization proclaiming new hope for nations struggling to pull themselves out of poverty, economics has little to offer them on how this might be done. In short, the discipline's abandonment of its early fascination with culture has rendered it speechless to those who most need its help today.

Culture Does Seem to Matter

Why do some countries do very well, while others fail to develop, even when all the requisite economic factors seem to be in place? How can we explain the repeated failure of African nations, even when aid is given in great supply, to develop their economy? Why are countries like Indonesia and the Philippines, even with a strong resource base and a well educated population, so resistant to development? For that matter, what is there to explain the slow economic growth rates of the Pacific nations?

Most development economists might explain these inequalities by appealing to the list of conditions that must be met for an economy to develop. Good governance is seen as a prerequisite of development: the political system should be stable; laws must be clearly promulgated and enforced so that contractual agreements will be honored; and government officials should not be corrupt or inefficient. Moreover, land should be available at a fair rate for business opportunities; foreign investment should be encouraged; and the bureaucratic procedures for applying for a business permit should not be too onerous.

There may be something to be said for this list, but it still doesn't deal with the more fundamental issue of how culture impacts on development. Why do some ethnic groups do so well in business that they leave others in the dust, even when these ethnic groups are minorities in other cultures? Amy Chua raises this question in her much acclaimed book World on Fire.

In her work we learn that ethnic Chinese in the Philippines, accounting for less than two percent of the population, control 60% of the nation's private economy, including the country's four major airlines and almost all the country's banks, hotels and shopping malls. But it's not just in the Philippines that Chinese ethnic minorities have made their mark. They have come to dominate business in other parts of Southeast Asia as well-especially Indonesia, Thailand, Burma and Malaysia. Even closer to home, Chinese have distinguished themselves in the Solomons, Tonga, and in Majuro, triggering occasional reactions from the local populations.

Chinese are far from the only group to achieve such success. As Chua points out in her book, no matter where we look around the world, we will find examples of what she calls "dominant minorities"-ethnic groups that have demonstrated a remarkable ability to succeed in business wherever they may live. The Lebanese have become the entrepreneurs in Sierra Leone and other parts of West Africa, while Indians have assumed the same reputation in East Africa. In Russia, six of the seven billionaires following the privatization of public resources less than a decade ago were Jewish. For years, Chua points out, the Croats had enjoyed a much higher standard of living than the majority Serbs in what was formerly known as Yugoslavia. In South America, she goes on to point out, those of European descent have long held economic power over their darker-skinned compatriots.

Clearly, some ethnic groups seem to be far more successful in business than others. Unfortunately, their financial success can incite violent retaliation against these groups, for they are usually small minorities in their adopted countries. During the last two decades, just as globalization was being trumpeted as the big leveling force through the world, uprisings have occurred in one country after another to strip the dominant business minorities of their economic power. Many of these-in Mugabe's Zimbabwe, in post-Suharto Indonesia, in Rwanda, in Serbia, and in Ethiopia-sought to redress the imbalance by expropriation of holdings, expulsion of ethnic minorities, or worst of all by genocidal wars. Apart from the enormous human suffering generated by the conflicts themselves, further misery followed. The nations that had sought to reclaim what they felt was justly theirs became even more impoverished when the people to whom businesses were handed off could not make them work.

Even so, the summons to a globalization that will offer all ethnic groups equal opportunity continues to ring out. To the extent that it remains a hollow call and a false hope, Chua warns us, it will spur further outbursts of ethnic violence fueled by frustration.

Why the Differences?

If some cultural groups seem to do better than others, what would explain the differences? The real intent of this question, of course, is to discover what might be done to compensate for these differences and cancel the competitive disadvantages that some cultures seem to bear in this age of globalization.

The inequality of cultures is one of the themes explored by Gregory Clark in his recent Farewell to Alms, which he subtitles A Brief Economic History of the World. It was no accident, he argues, that the Industrial Revolution occurred in Great Britain and not some other nation. Although his book is more concerned with the antecedents of the Industrial Revolution than the transforming impact of this landmark event on subsequent history, he points out that it gave rise to what he calls the "Great Divergence." The Industrial Revolution may have brought about enormous changes in production technology, but it left many nations impoverished just as it made others wealthy. After the mid-19th century, the heyday of the Industrial Revolution, the differences in national income and standard of living around the globe became even greater than they ever had been before, Clark points out, and the differences continue to widen with each passing decade.

Why was Britain in a unique position to give birth to the Industrial Revolution? And why did the effects of the Industrial Revolution vary so greatly from one part of the globe to another, from one nation to another? Clark maintains that Britain's development was not a sudden leap forward that was propelled by the invention of a few power-driven machines. It was gradual, he maintains, taking place over the course of several hundred years prior to the 19th century. In his way of thinking, the Industrial Revolution would have never occurred had it not been for the changes in values that were happening for centuries before. From the High Middle Ages on, following the Magna Carta in the 13th century that limited royal authority, Britain had the stable political, legal and economic institutions so often touted as the preconditions for economic growth.

But such institutions of themselves do not generate economic progress, Clark maintains. Stable political institutions, a reliable legal system, predictable land values and functioning markets were the necessary but not sufficient conditions for the economic take off Britain experienced when new sources of power were harnessed. They did, however, lead to the gradual development of precisely that set of deep cultural changes, especially a sense of competitiveness and a strong work ethic, that was required if sudden technological breakthroughs were have to have any real impact on the society. The data that the author presents to us offers a picture of a society that was losing its taste for violence even as its homicide rate was dropping, a society with high population growth among the well-to-do, one in which people had to work hard and long to gain a competitive advantage over their peers, a society that was increasingly literate and patient. These traits served people so well in Britain, Clark adds, that they would have been passed on by means of social Darwinism and possibly even by a genetic selection process as well. This cluster of traits, usually associated with the middle class, gave people the edge in surviving, just as quickness of reaction, strong legs and a good aim might have in a much earlier age and in a very different milieu.

All of this predated the Industrial Revolution, Clark points out, so that when the steam engines and other new means of production were developed in the early 19th century, the British could utilize them to expand their economy many times over. By contrast, when India was introduced to the technology later in the 19th century, the results were far different. The power-driven cotton mills that had spurred such a startling economic burst in Britain were introduced to India but never offered the country the same competitive advantage. The productivity of British mill workers, thanks to the very traits that Clark has described for us, was so far greater than that of their Indian counterparts that even though hourly rates for Indian employees were merely one-fourth of British labor, British-run mills were far more cost-efficient than Indian mills. Clark notes that to compensate for the greater per-person productivity of British employees and to get the Indian mills operating at maximum output, Indian mills would typically hire many more employees. But this boosted labor costs beyond what they would be in a British mill, making the Indian-run mills non-competitive in the end.

So, in the end, it was people and the values they had absorbed over the years, not the power-driven mills or any other form of advanced technology, that had made the difference.

Values and Attitudes

"Does Culture Affect Economic Outcomes?" is the title of an intriguing paper written two years ago by Luigi Guiso, Paola Sapienza and Luigi Zingales. The paper offers tantalizing suggestions as to which values matter most when economic development is at stake.

The first writer to propose a cultural explanation for underdevelopment, the authors tell us, was the political scientist Edward Banfield in his 1958 volume The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. He attributes the slow economic growth in southern Italy to the excessive pursuit of narrow self-interest by people who have never learned to trust anything outside their family. Following this lead in his own 1993 book, Robert Putnam offers evidence that those areas in Italy that enjoyed free city states centuries earlier have a much better track record today than those places in southern Italy that never had the benefit of such civic institutions. When these institutions are effective, people are prepared to invest in social capital. Development of a sense of trust is critical here, it is suggested, and this occurs over a long period of time as people come to believe in something beyond their own extended family. (I have to admit that when I read this I immediately thought of Chuuk, a cultural area that traditionally had very few civic institutions and so might have been slow in developing the public trust these authors regard as so important.)

In an even more recent book, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations, David Landes concludes that the success of national economies is driven by cultural factors more than anything else. Thrift, hard work, tenacity, honesty and tolerance are the cultural factors that make all the difference, he suggests. In his view, Max Weber was right after all in suggesting that social attitudes and values have the decisive say on what economies will succeed and which will fail.

Guido Tabellini, in a working paper written three years ago, makes an attempt to offer real evidence for the impact of culture on economic development. Using as his cultural constellation a set of four values-trust, belief in the importance of individual effort, generalized morality and autonomy-he finds that yearly economic growth and per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) are higher in those regions throughout Europe that exhibit higher levels of these four cultural values.

All of this merely confirms what Amy Chua suggests and Gregory Clark tries to document-namely, that modern technology alone will never be able to turn around an economy and to boost the standard of living among a population. The development of a mindset, with accompanying values and habits, is a big part of the equation. Formal education may contribute to this, but possibly not so much because it imparts new information and hones skills as because it inculcates a new view of the world and concomitant values.

This conclusion is not encouraging for less developed parts of the world. At one time, economists felt that sufficient capital, especially through national savings, might catapult nations into a flight path of economic growth. Lately, it has become more fashionable to focus on the institutions, political and economic, to ensure that the ground is prepared for the bountiful economic harvest to come. But a number of recent authors, proponents of the cultural dimension of economic development, are suggesting that the creation of such political and economic institutions may have taken centuries. Even once they are in place, there may be need for still further cultivation of attitudes and values before a country is fertile for economic development.

Where do the island nations of Micronesia stand in all this?

Closer to Home

Many parts of the world have been written off as resistant to development. We may think of most of Africa, parts of Latin America, the Middle East, and a few of the countries in Southeast Asia. Of course, many of these countries still lack the reliable institutions, beginning with stable government and the rule of law, that are a requisite for development according to today's canon. Then there is the Pacific, which has shown disappointing economic growth rates over the past decade or two. If the authors we have cited are on the right track in suggesting that historical antecedents of a people produce a cluster of values and beliefs that foster economic development, then it might be enlightening to measure Micronesian island societies against this cluster.

Overall, Micronesia, like the rest of the Pacific, probably does not rank very high in those cultural value and attitudes that have been identified as helpful in promoting economic development today. This is not an indictment of Micronesia or the other Pacific Island cultures. Nor is it to suggest that these islands suffer from corruption or political instability or some of the other problems that plague less fortunate countries in other parts of the world. Indeed, the traditional Micronesian value cluster was clearly well suited to survival in small islands in the past. Yet, the same value set that allowed islanders to maintain harmony and support one another throughout good times and hard times in the past is not equally well suited to building a modern economy. In other words, Micronesia simply does not enjoy the same cultural advantages that led Britain to prosperity after the Industrial Revolution or which have given Chinese and Lebanese entrepreneurs the competitive edge they enjoy even after leaving their own country to settle in another.

What Would It Take?

What would it take to develop the set of values that a line of authors, extending from Adam Smith to contemporary economists, see as fundamental conditions for achieving real economic development? Must we wait centuries for this to happen, as Britain and the US did, or can this process be accelerated?

Improved education for the population is an almost automatic response, as Amy Chua points out, but she admits that research on the impact of education does not support the conclusion that this will work. She goes on to point out that much more work needs to be done on the interplay of culture with economic success, and writes that even if the relationship between the two were pinpointed, leveling the playing field between ethnic groups "will be a painfully slow process, taking generations if it is possible at all."

Gregory Clark offers evidence to support his conviction that the path to economic development is to increase worker output, whether in a textile mill or a computer lab. He traces the steady rise of Japanese worker output against that of Indian mill employees during the early years of the 20th century, showing that by the 1930s Japan had outproduced India and had come to dominate the market. The greater efficiency of Japanese workers during this time was a result of their strong discipline, which in turn stemmed from their cultural values.

A growing number of authors seem to agree that economic growth will take more than an infusion of investment capital, more than an import of the latest technology, even more than dependable political and economic institutions. A constellation of cultural values suited for modern business seems to be a critical ingredient as well, although no one has identified these values with precision, to say nothing of devising a strategy for inculcating these values in developing populations. For now, we can only conclude that in the contest for economic development the playing field is far from level. The world is not nearly as flat as Friedman exuberantly proclaimed.

Meanwhile, the small nations of Micronesia are not left hanging in the wind. They enjoy substantial dollar amounts of aid from the US, access to the US for those who can not find employment at home, and a measure of successful business in the islands. What they do not enjoy, however, is the cultural climate that is deemed essential in order to turn the islands into a whirlwind of economic activity and to stimulate the level of growth that outsiders had hoped to witness.

At present in Micronesia, money is viewed as a means to more meaningful ends than simply expanding one's financial wealth. In island culture strictly economic considerations are limited by other considerations, ones that individuals often judge to offer them greater personal advantages than multiplying their money. These considerations fall under three headings: security, status and solidarity.

None of this is reprehensible, but neither does it reflect the value set that will create millionaires and promote the rapid growth that the islands seek today. Although entirely reasonable to island people, choices like these can be mystifying to consultants in that they seem to flout what should be irresistible economic incentives so as to achieve other trivial gains. But what is "trivial" from one cultural viewpoint is not necessarily so from another. Here is where cultural values impact on economic choices, where an island-oriented cost-benefit analysis defies what outsiders would consider "common sense." Here, too, is where the conversation on economic development must begin.

But what happens when Micronesians are plucked from their own cultural soil and are transplanted in the US? What is the effect of this relocation on the set of cultural values that tend to inhibit economic development? The tens of thousands of Micronesians who have emigrated to the US to find jobs and a new home there could provide a population sample for research into the speed with which cultural values changes. A study of these emigrants could offer insights into the impact of their new cultural surroundings on these islanders, even as it helps us answer the question of whether the cultural changes needed to improve economic development can be accelerated.

Francis X. Hezel, SJ

Why did it take so long for humans to have the Industrial Revolution?

Tyler Cowen

Marginal Revolution blog

That's a reader request from the especially loyal Harrison Brookie.  First, you might wish to go back and read the MR reviews and debates of Greg Clark's Farewell to Alms,

More generally, extended periods of economic growth require that technologies of defense outweigh technologies of predation.  They may also require that the successful defender, at the same time, has good enough technology to predate someone else and accumulate a sizable surplus.  Parts of Europe took a good deal from the New World and this may have mattered a good deal.

Building a strong enough state to protect markets from other states is very hard to do; at the same time the built state has to avoid crushing those markets itself.  That's a very delicate balanceChina had wonderful technology for its time and was the richest part of the world for centuries but never succeeded in this endeavor, not for long at least.

England was fortunate to be an islandStarting in the early seventeenth century, England had many decades of ongoing, steady growth.  Later, coal and the steam engine kicked in at just the right time.  English political institutions were "good enough" as well and steadily improving, for the most part.

Christianity was important for transmitting an ideology of individual rights and natural lawAs McCloskey and Mokyr stress, the Industrial Revolution was in part about ideas.

There are numerous other factors, but putting those ones together -- and no others -- already makes an Industrial Revolution very difficult to achieve.  It did happen, it probably would have happened somewhere, sooner or later, but its occurrence was by no means easy to achieve.  The Greeks had steam engines, proto-computers, and brilliant philosophers and writers, but still they did not come close to a breakthrough.

One question is how long the Roman Empire would have had to last to generate an Industrial Revolution and don't mention the Eastern Empire smartypants.

If you are asking why the Industrial Revolution did not occur in the Mesozoic age, or other earlier times, genetic factors play a role as well.

 

 

Food-Price Rise Puts Focus on Speculators

By SAMEER MOHINDRU

SINGAPORE—The run-up in global commodity prices is stirring debate in a number of countries over the role of financial speculators, a prospect that could fuel a regulatory backlash by governments keen to control food prices.

View Full Image

 

European Pressphoto Agency

An Indian vendor taking money from customer at a market in Mumbai.

 

The prices of many commodities undoubtedly would have risen anyway in response to recent supply disruptions and rising demand. But some political leaders are raising questions about how much investors such as commodities traders and hedge funds might be contributing to the run-up. That could leader to anger among consumers and draw yet more fire from politicians on the dangers of derivatives trading.

Already, many developing nations, including China and India are instigating price controls on foodstuffs to combat inflation and ward off the kind of discontent that led to riots in 2008. France, which holds the presidency of the Group of 20, is pushing for tighter regulation and transparency in the trading of commodities, including derivatives trading.

In China, after cotton, sugar, rubber and corn prices hit record highs in November, the government asked futures exchanges to raise trading margins, in some cases to more than 10%.

"We share the view that commodity price fluctuations have been, from time to time, excessive, and destabilize the growth of the economy," Rintaro Tamaki, Japan's vice minister of finance for international affairs, said last week.

Excess speculation from "investment tourists" aggravates instability, sending signals that aren't substantiated by fundamentals, said Abdolreza Abbassian, secretary for the Intergovernmental Group on Foodgrains at the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization.

Similar sentiments swirling around a tripling of oil prices between 2004 and 2008 contributed to limits currently being hammered out in the U.S. on the positions financial buyers can take in a number of commodities. The recent run-up has complicated debate on the final rules there.

On futures exchanges in the U.S., the world's biggest grain exporter, aggregate net long speculative positions in 14 major agricultural derivative contracts hit a record high of 104 million metric tons in November, well above the previous peak of 78 million tons in March 2008, an Australia & New Zealand Banking Group report said. Long positions are bets on rising prices.

That's a big swing from earlier last year, when speculators were net short in U.S. agricultural futures, meaning investors were largely betting that prices would fall.

Parsing out the impact of speculators can be difficult.

According to Nobuyuki Chino, president of Unipac Grain, a Tokyo-based commodities trading company, U.S. wheat prices would be closer to $6 a bushel compared with current prices of around $8 a bushel had there been no speculative interest in wheat. Corn should be trading around $5 a bushel versus $6.5 a bushel now, and soybeans around $13.20, compared with $14, he said.

Others are skeptical of the claims. "I've seen some sort of studies [suggesting] speculation has added 20% to 30% to market prices, but they are never substantiated. What you can say is the futures markets at times trade at substantial premia to the underlying cash market," said Ann Berg, a consultant to the U.N.'s food and agriculture agency.

With Asian derivatives exchanges gaining market share in recent years, there has been a surge in interest from global investors who want to park their funds in derivative products in the region, without the hassle of owning or storing physical commodities.

In India, for example, the cumulative value of futures trading in commodities in the nine months to December rose 50% to 82.7 trillion rupees ($1.817 trillion), according to data from the Forward Markets Commission, regulator of the country's futures exchanges.

The Indian government has selectively suspended futures trading in politically sensitive food items in the past and authorities are still reluctant to lift export controls despite growing domestic stocks.

 

THE POOR NEED CAPITALISM
------------------------------------------------------------------------

The Left's version of recent economic history boils down to one    
terrible fact: The distribution of income has gradually become more    
unequal.  Within the United States, that fact is incontrovertible.    
It is not clear, however, that increased inequality has been bad, says    
economist Kevin A. Hassett.

Inequality is, after all, the foundation of a capitalist society.     
When individuals work hard, or innovate, they receive outsized rewards.    
 When others see those rewards, they are motivated to work hard    
and innovate.  As the lottery-ticket market has demonstrated, the    
bigger the prize, the bigger the motivation, explains Hassett.

A landmark new study by economists Maxim Pinkovskiy and Xavier    
Sala-i-Martin set out to study changes in the world distribution of    
income by gathering data from many different countries.  As a    
byproduct of their work, they are able to count the number of    
individuals who live on $1 per day or less, a key measure of    
poverty.  According to their calculations:
   o   The number of people living in poverty so defined has    
       plummeted, from 967,574,000 in 1970 to 350,436,000 in 2006, a    
       decrease of a whopping 64 percent.
   o   The biggest factor in the reduction was the emergence of    
       middle classes in previously poverty stricken China and India.
   o   The spread of capitalism to other countries has similarly    
       been followed by prosperity; the trend is even more impressive    
       if one considers that the world population skyrocketed over    
       that time, increasing by 3 billion.

If the trend continues for just 40 more years, poverty will have been    
essentially eradicated from the globe.  And capitalism will have    
done it, says Hassett.  Socialism offers itself as an alternative    
to capitalism that is more just to the poor.  To test that view,    
the authors reconstruct the distribution of income for the countries of    
the former Soviet Union.  Back in the Communist days, poverty was    
much, much higher in the Soviet Union than it is today.

There are those who have argued that the current financial crisis has    
served as proof that capitalism is a failed ideology.  The work of    
Pinkovskiy and Sala-i-Martin suggests that there are about a billion    
people whose lives prove otherwise, says Hassett.

Source: Kevin A. Hassett, "The Poor Need Capitalism,"    
National Review, November 23, 2009; based upon: Maxim Pinkovskiy and    
Xavier Sala-i-Martin, "Parametric Estimations of the World    
Distribution of Income," National Bureau of Economic Research,    
Working Paper No. 15433, October 2009.

For text:
http://www.thefreelibrary.com/The+poor+need+capitalism.-a0211555573
For study:
http://www.nber.org/papers/w15433
For more on Economic Issues:      
http://www.ncpa.org/sub/dpd/?Article_Category=17

 

 

 

http://blogs.wsj.com/economics/?mod=marketbeat

Oct 8, 2009
1:22 PM

Q&A: Economist De Soto Warns of ‘Huge Problems Coming’ in Property Crisis

Posted by Michael Casey

Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto, who campaigns for property right reform as means of attacking poverty, is the subject of The Power of the Poor, a documentary showing on PBS at 10:00 pm Thursday, Oct. 8. (Local listing times may vary.) He talked recently with Michael Casey about the impact that the global crisis has had on the world’s poor. Excerpts from that interview follow.

How has the global crisis and the policy response to it played out among the poor of the developing world?

De Soto: Well, in Peru, for example, the stimulus effort has meant that we have managed to get enough credit to the cities such that they are doing all right. But in the poorest and most populous parts of the Peruvian jungle, from January to June, exports have gone down by 57% and production has gone down by 25% to 27%. The effect has been huge.  In these kinds of places around the world, which includes marginalized areas of cities, or anywhere where you’ve got an informal economy, where credit can’t go because there are no addresses, no guarantees and no collateral, the stimulus programs can only trickle down. They can’t get in directly because the people have no way to identify themselves vis-à-vis the benefits that have come in.

What are the political implications of this widening gap between those who have property titles and those who don’t?

De Soto: What it means is that we’ve got huge problems coming. What happened to us in the Amazon area of Peru [where 22 police were killed in clashes with protesting indigenous residents] is something that is only now beginning. It could explode. All of a sudden, everywhere, we’ll see mines being taken over, negotiations with trade unions breaking down, and [leftist leaders like] Hugo Chavez and Evo Morales on the move. Social cleavage – or a class cleavage if you want to use the Marixst term – is on the rise.

Mineral and agricultural commodity prices fell sharply last year, but monetary stimulus and inflation fears have helped drive a rebound. What does this mean for people who live in poorer regions that produce these commodities?

De Soto: The stimulus means we have twice as many dollars and twice as much of any currency in the system as a year ago. The question is: When are those dollars, those euros or those renmimbi going to hit the market? A lot of people are banking on central banks doing the easiest thing and letting inflation go. So there is a rush for commodities. And what does that mean? That there’s a mad land grab going. As we speak, whether it’s the Chinese or big agro-industrial companies, they are all buying up land in Africa, in Latin America. And the thing is those poor farmers, and those hunter and gatherer tribes, they always happen to be right where you find things. But if it’s all untitled property that belongs to tribes or to individuals from tribes and there is no recognition of that, we are heading into another huge class cleavage situation.

What’s the solution?

De Soto: Well, the solution to that cleavage doesn’t come with more stimulus because stimulus will only create more inflation. The solution lies in property rights. When you are selling cocoa futures, for example, nobody comes to market with the cocoa in their hand; they come with a piece of paper that says they have a claim to the cocoa in the future. All markets work on this basis of property rights. You are selling title over something, you are not really selling “it.” And if you have a majority of the world that is still not titled in those assets that are in greatest demand, and with twice as much money out there, we are heading for one big storm.

 

 

BRAZIL BATTLES THE "OIL CURSE"
------------------------------------------------------------------------
 
Ever since the Brazilian state energy company Petrobras struck oil in    
giant fields deep below the floor of the Atlantic, the mood in    
Brasília has been practically euphoric.  The discovery may    
produce 80 billion barrels of oil for Brazil, but beating the "oil    
curse" -- an affliction visited on oil-rich nations from Africa to    
Asia, where a glut of petrodollars guts industries, warps politics,    
fuels tyrants and leaves the poor even poorer  -- remains a key    
requisite to profiting from the find, says Newsweek.  
 
There are, however, reasons for hope for Brazil, says Newsweek:
 
   o   The country has managed past discoveries well.
 
   o   The country's current regulatory model is well respected    
       within the oil industry.
 
   o   The model guarantees competition by auctioning concessions to    
       private companies.
 
But a new law -- now before Congress -- would replace the existing    
model with "production sharing," a model favored by    
autocratic governments, a model favored by Saudi Arabia and Venezuela,    
says Newsweek:
 
   o   The law grants state oil company Petrobras a 30 percent stake    
       in all new deals.
 
   o   The government would also retain veto power over all drilling    
       contracts, leaving it and not the market to pick winners.
 
Brasilia agues that taking the reins of the accounts will help the    
country avoid drilling too much oil too quickly, but the belief is    
rooted on the belief that bureaucrats make good businessmen.     
Brazil has been down this road before and the result was waste and    
slower growth, says Newsweek.
 
Source:  Mac Margolis, "Brazil Battles the 'Oil Curse,'    
Newsweek, October 12, 2009.
 For more on International Issues:      
 http://www.ncpa.org/sub/dpd/?Article_Category=26     

 MAY 22, 2009

Against the Human Development Index

Bryan Caplan

The authors of the "U.S. Unemployment Rate Now as High as Europe" report have turned down my bet.  One of the authors did however counter-offer a bet that Scandinavia's scores on the Human Development Index would beat America's at the end of the Obama administration.  That's funny, because I was already planning to blog against the usefulness of the HDI today, provoked by the CEPR report's remark that:

The case for the superiority of the U.S. model was always exaggerated.  For one thing, it tended to ignore the relatively lower performance of the U.S. on broader quality-of-life measures like the Human Development Index.

Now what exactly is the HDIThe one-line explanation is that it gives "equal weights" to GDP per capita, life expectancy, and educationBut it's more complicated than that, because scores on each of the three measures are bounded between 0 and 1.  This effectively means that a country of immortals with infinite per-capita GDP would get a score of .666 (lower than South Africa and Tajikistan) if its population were illiterate and never went to school.

So what are the main problems with the HDI?

1. I can see giving equal weights to GDP per capita and life expectancy.  But education?  As a professor and a snob, I understand the appeal (though a measure of opera consumption would be even better).  But in terms of the actual if not professed values of normal human beings, televisions and cars are a lot more important than books.

2. When you take a closer look at the HDI's education measure, it's especially bogus.   2/3rds of the weight comes from the literacy rate.  At least that's not ridiculous.  But the other 1/3 comes from the Gross Enrollment Index - the fraction of the population enrolled in primary, secondary, or tertiary education.  OK, I feel a reductio ad absurdum coming on.  To max out your education score, you have to turn 100% of your population into students!

3
. The HDI purportedly gives equal weights to three different outcomes, but bounding the results between 0 and 1 builds in a massive bias against GDPGDP per capita has grown fantastically during the last two centuries, and will continue to do so.  In reality, there's plenty of room left for further improvement even in rich countries.  But the HDI doesn't allow this.  Since rich countries are already close to the upper bound, the HDI effectively defines their future progress on this dimension out of existence. 

To a lesser extent, the same goes for life expectancy: While it's roughly doubled over the last two centuries, dying at 85 is not, contrary to the HDI, approximately equal in value to immortality.

The clear winners from this weighting scheme, of course, are the literacy and enrollment measures, both of which have upper bounds that are imposed by logic rather than fiat.

4.  The ultimate problem with the HDI, though, is lack of ambition It effectively proclaims an "end of history" where Scandinavia is the pinnacle of human achievement.  Admittedly, I've never visited Scandinavia.  But when I see it for the first time this August, I'm pretty sure I won't say to myself, "Wow, it can't get any better than this!"

At this point, you might ask, "Yes, but will you take the HDI bet, Bryan?"  Nope. 
Scandinavia comes out on top according to the HDI because the HDI is basically a measure of how Scandinavian your country isWhile Obama is moving us in that direction, I don't think he's going to be able to take us all the way there.

CATEGORIES: Cross-country Comparisons

 

FOREIGN AID KEEPS LATIN AMERICA POOR
------------------------------------------------------------------------
 
Latin America remains poor and backward not despite multilateral    
"assistance" but, in a large part, because of it, says Wall    
Street Journal columnist Mary Anastasia O'Grady.  The    
Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) has been going at the problem of    
poverty in Latin America since 1959, but it hasn't acted alone.     
In the postwar period the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund    
and untold bilateral agencies have blanketed the region with aid.     
World-wide foreign aid has boomed. 
 
According to the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development    
(OECD):
 
   o   In 2008, total net official development assistance (ODA) from    
       members of the OECD's Development Assistance Committee (DAC)    
       rose by 10.2 percent in real terms to $119.8 billion.
 
   o   This is the highest dollar figure ever recorded.
 
Does it follow that poverty persists because the amounts have been just    
too measly to do the job, asks O'Grady? 
 
A 2006 paper titled "Foreign Aid, Income Inequality and    
Poverty," from the research department of the IDB itself, looked    
at the period 1971-2002 and found "some weak evidence that foreign    
aid is conducive to the improvement of the distribution of income    
[sic].  When the quality of institutions is taken into account,    
however, this result is not robust.  This finding is consistent    
with recent empirical research on aid ineffectiveness in achieving    
economic growth or promoting democratic institutions."
 
In a recent book titled "Lessons From the Poor" about    
successful entrepreneurs in the developing world, researcher Alvaro    
Vargas Llosa echoes these insights.  "The decisive    
element" in bringing a society out of poverty is "the    
development of the entrepreneurial reserves that exist in its men and    
women," Vargas Llosa writes.  "The institutions that    
grant more freedom to their citizens and more security to their    
citizens' possessions are those that best facilitate the accumulation    
of wealth."
 
It is obvious that economic liberty and property rights are the key    
drivers of development, and that there is no correlation between the    
volume of foreign aid a country receives and its respect for these    
values, says the Journal.  
 
Source: Mary Anastasia O'Grady, "Aid Keeps Latin America Poor; For    
real progress, they need the means to accumulate wealth," Wall    
Street Journal, April 6, 2009.
 
For text:
 
&
amp;
amp;
amp;
amp;
lt;
span style="FONT-SIZE: 9pt">http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123897316163590919.html 
 
 
For more on International Issues:      
 
http://www.ncpa.org/sub/dpd/?Article_Category=26      

 

 

http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/philg/2009/03/16/how-rich-coun

 

How Rich Countries Die

philg - March 16, 2009 @ 2:27 pm · Filed under Uncategorized

This is a book report on The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities , by Mancur Olson.  There isn’t a whole lot about how nations pulled themselves out of their medieval stagnation (see A Farewell to Alms for that), so a better title for this still-in-print book from 1982 would be “How Rich Countries Die.”

Table 1.1 shows annual rates of growth in per-capita GDP for each of three decades, the 1950s, 60s, and 70s, in a range of rich countries.  Contrary to our perception of the U.S. as a growth dynamo and the Europeans as sclerotic, France and Germany tremendously outperformed the U.S., as did most of the other countries.  If we have grown larger it is because our population has expanded much faster than the European countries.

Chapter 2 summarizes Olson’s groundbreaking work on how interest groups work to reduce a society’s efficiency and GDP.  Some of this work seems obvious in retrospect and indeed Adam Smith noted that businessmen rarely met without conspiring against the public interest.  There are a handful of automobile producers and millions of automobile consumers.  It makes sense for an automobile company, acting individually, to lobby Congress for tariffs.  The company will reap 20-40 percent of the benefits of the tariff.  It doesn’t make sense for an individual consumer, however, to lobby Congress.  It will cost him millions of dollars to lobby against Congress and preventing the tariff will save him only a few thousand dollars on his next car purchase.  The economy suffers because some resources that would have been put to productive use are instead hanging around Washington and because cars are more expensive than they should be.

Labor unions are a drag on the economy, but a labor union that represents all of the workers in a company will be less of a drag than a union that represents only a small percentage of workers in each of hundreds of companies.  The single-company labor union will have some interest in keeping its host company alive by not bleeding it too much.  A union that represents only 10 percent of a company’s workers will recognize that it can drive up compensation to double or triple the market-clearing wage without, by itself, killing the host company.

Citizens won’t bother to inform themselves about public policy, especially the details.  Given the lack of influence of a single vote, it doesn’t make sense for a non-specialist to invest the time.  Olson says this is why we have a progressive income tax, obvious to all voters, and a lot of obscure loopholes that benefit the wealthy and influential.  He notes that the benefits of Medicare and Medicaid to the old and the poor are publicized, not the fact that they are “implemented or administered in ways that resulted in large increases in income for prosperous physicians and other providers of medical care” because “the many smaller choices needed to implement these programs are influenced primarily by a minority of organized providers.”

Chapter 3:It takes a long time for special interest groups to form.  Olson cites the fact that it was in 1851, a century after the start of the Industrial Revolution, that the first modern trade union formed in Britain.  The longer that a society remains stable, the more freighted down with special interest groups it becomes.

The president of the U.S. would like to see greater economic efficiency in the U.S. as a whole.  Individual congressmen, however, will push for pork-barrel legislation that benefits their district even if the cost to the overall economy is hundreds of times greater than the benefit (their constituents will pay 1/435th of the cost and receive 100 percent of the benefit).  This leads to a perennial conflict between the president and Congress.

Unions or cartels of businesses slow an economy’s response to change because they require the assent of many members in order to effect a change.  This makes wages and prices much stickier than in a classical free-market economy.  Unions will negotiate agreements that favor senior workers at the expense of junior members and young people just entering the workforce.

Olson would not be surprised by the current auto industry bailout: “Special-interest groups also slow growth by reducing the rate at which resources are reallocated from one activity or industry to another in response to new technologies or conditions.  One obvious way in which they do so is lobbying for bail-outs of failing firms, thereby delaying or preventing the shift of resources to areas where they would have a greater productivity.”

Special interest groups create complexity,  by getting special rules established for their benefit, and thrive on complexity.  If a tax or tariff code were only three pages long, an average citizen would be able to spot the sweetheart deals.  If a code runs to 1000 pages, however, nobody will ever understand all of it.

Special interest groups may create government regulation.  Prior to the Ford Administration’s mid-1970s push to deregulate railroads, trucking, and airlines, for example, the U.S. government was very effective at ensuring profits and excluding new entrants to the market.

Chapter 4 compares countries in the post-World War II period.  Olson says that Germany and Japan did well because their special interest groups were shattered by military defeat.  When new labor unions formed in Germany and Japan, they tended to be very broad-based and therefore had an incentive in the overall welfare of their societies.

“Great Britain, the major nation with the longest immunity from dictatorship, invasion, and revolution, has had in this century a lower rate of growth than other large, developed democracies. … Britain has [a] powerful network of special-interest organizations.  The number and power of its trade unions need no description. [Olson wrote this book just as Margaret Thatcher was coming to power.]  The venerability and power of its professional associations is also striking.  … Britain also has a strong farmer’s organization and a great many trade associations.”

“[Britain's interest groups] are narrow rather than encompassing.  For example, in a single factory there are often many different trade unions, each with a monopoly over a different craft or category of workers…”

Olson notes that slow growth can’t be due to something inherent in the British character, because the country was the world’s fastest growing from 1750 until 1850.

Olson cites a study by Murrell testing the hypothesis that Britain’s slow growth was due to special interest groups that took time to form.  Murrell looked at new versus old industries in Germany and Britain.  The disparity in growth rates was significantly larger in Britain than in Germany.

Britain during the time of the Industrial Revolution had more social mobility and less class consciousness than other European nations.  Napoleon and totalitarianism destroyed the Continent’s nobility, reversing the relationship between Britain and the rest of Europe.

Olson preempts the question of “How come the Swiss aren’t poor given that they’ve had stability for so many centuries?” by looking at their constitution, which “makes it extremely difficult to pass new legislation.  This makes it difficult for lobbies to get their way and thus greatly limits Switzerland’s losses from special interest legislation.”

Olson asks why the U.S., given its stable government and lack of invasions, hasn’t done very poorly.  The first answer is that the U.S. has done poorly, growing slower than France, Germany, and Japan.  The second answer is that the U.S. is not uniform.  Some parts are relatively recently settled (the West) and/or relatively recently recovered from the Civil War (the South).  It turns out that these are precisely the regions of the U.S. that have enjoyed the fastest rates of growth:  “the longer a state has been settled and the longer the time it has had to accumulate special interest groups, the slower its rate of growth.”

Chapter 5 looks at medieval guilds and foreign trade.  Olson finds that the countries with the lowest tariffs had the highest growth rates.  The countries with the fewest restrictions on immigrant labor had the highest rates of growth in per-capita income.

Chapter 6 is titled “Inequality, Discrimination and Development.”  Japan’s history is mined for evidence supporting Olson’s theory.  The country was stable until the mid-1800s.  This led to “tolls, tariffs, regulations, and legal monopolies”; the country was a basketcase economically.  The nation was opened up via gunboat diplomacy, which shattered the feudal system and high tariffs.  The country grew so quickly that it defeated Russia in 1905 and came close to humiliating the U.S. in 1941.

Olson quotes Nehru explaining that Muslims were able to conquer India because of the “growing rigidity and exclusiveness of the Indian social system as represented chiefly by the caste system.”  Olson compares the caste system to the medieval guilds.  The barring of marriage outside of one’s caste is explained by the desire of a caste to retain the fruits of its economic exclusivity.

South Africa is next.  The mine owners wanted to hire mostly Africans because they could be paid less than whites.  The trade unions were controlled by whites and wanted to force the mines to employ at least one white for every 3.5 black workers.  Bitter strikes led ultimately to the rise of white supremacist political parties and legislation limiting employment opportunities for blacks.  Restrictions on labor were naturally followed by restrictions on social interaction and marriage.

Olson notes that special-interest groups increase inequality in a society.  A union prevents companies from hiring black workers at the same wages at whites.  A caste system prevents someone from rising above the station to which he was born.  Effective lobbying turns welfare or health care programs into cash cows for government workers or health care providers.

Chapter 7 is very timely, being about stagflation and business cycles.  Olson points out that no standard economic theories explain how the U.S. and Britain could have suffered high unemployment rates for the full decade of the 1930s.  Keynesian economics could not explain the simultaneous high unemployment and high inflation of the 1970s.  Olson points out that no economic theory explains why “unemployment is more common among groups of lower skill and productivity, such as teenagers, disadvantaged racial minorities, and so on” (classical economics would have these folks working at the same rate as anyone else, but at lower wages).

Classical economics does not allow for involuntary unemployment.  If the labor supply increases or the economy worsens, wages should fall until everyone is working for a wage that clears the market and that enables employers to make a profit despite lower prices for final products.  “The main group that can have an interest in preventing the mutually profitable transactions between the involuntarily unemployed and employers is the workers with the same or competitive skills.”  In other words, a company would prefer to replace a $60 per hour 50-year-old unskilled white worker with two $15 per hour black teenagers who would get a lot more done, but the old whites will form a union and prevent the company from hiring the young blacks.  If the company does need to hire someone it will be stuck paying $60 per hour and it might as well hire someone with an advanced degree and a lot of skills, which explains why the unskilled are disproportionately unemployed.

How could the Great Depression have lasted so long?  Olson suggests assuming that a lot of prices are fixed by colluding business cartels and/or by government regulation.  The prices are fixed higher than they would be in a free market, which imposes costs on society and guarantees supranormal profits to cartel members.  If there is inflation, the losses to the economy from the cartel are ameliorated.  The fixed price is no longer than much higher than what would have been the market price.  In the event of deflation, however, the fixed price is now ridiculously high, demand for such an overpriced product plummets, and production plummets.  Investment in new factories will fall to zero almost immediately.

Olson divides the economy into a fixprice sector and a flexprice sector.  The fixed price part of the economy includes government workers, union workers, products produced by cartels, agriculture supported by government, and imported raw materials whose price is set on world markets.  The flexprice sector would include simple services such as cleaning houses and babysitting,  In the event of deflation, the output in the fixed price sector will collapse, driving a flood of young and newly unemployed workers into the flexprice sector.  The schoolteacher will continue to earn $100,000 per year and retire at 52.  The laid-off manufacturing worker will find that the market-clearing wage for cleaning houses is one third of what it was before the economic downturn.  This is in fact what happened during the Great Depression.  Folks who kept their jobs sailed through; folks tried to make a living as street vendors could not earn enough to eat.

“The economy that has a dense network of narrow special-interest organizations will be susceptible during periods of deflation … to depression or stagflation.”

Olson looks at the tough times of 1975-76, with the world reeling from an oil price shock, and finds that the U.S. had an unemployment rate of 8 percent compared to Germany’s 4.5 percent and Japan’s 2 percent.  Is that the only evidence that the U.S. is plagued with special interests?  No.  Phillip Cagan looked at U.S. price and output statistics since 1890 and “found that the tendency for prices to fall during recessions has declined over time.  … an increasing proportion of the effect of any reduction in aggregate demand shows up as a reduction in real output.”  [in other words, when times get tough in the modern U.S., we shut down our factories rather than running them with lower wages and lower prices for finished goods; in the event of deflation reducing collectible property taxes, a city will fire half of its schoolteachers rather than cut any teacher's wage]

Conclusion

Olson showed back in 1982 that modern macroeconomic theory was basically worthless in developed stable countries.  Macroeconomics posits a free market in which wages and prices adjust dynamically.  That applies to an ever-smaller sector of the U.S. economy.  We have a rapidly growing governnment that directly or indirectly employs more than one third of our workers, many of whom are unionized.  We have a health care system that consumes 16 percent of GDP and is staffed with doctors who restrict entry into the profession via their licensing cartel.  The financial services sector is about 10 percent of the economy and they now tap into taxpayer money to keep their bonuses flowing in bad times.  The automotive industry kept itself profitable over the years by successfully lobbying for import tariffs.  When the profits turned to losses, they successfully lobbied to have taxpayers pick up those losses.  A university-trained macroeconomist might be able to predict what will happen to babysitters in a depression, but not the price of cereal, the wage of a manufacturing worker, or the fate of those Americans who collect most of our national income (e.g., Wall Street, medical doctors, government workers).

A cashflow approach is much more effective for figuring out where we’re headed.  Money flows out to the folks on Wall Street who bankrupted their firms, to schoolteachers who’ve failed to teach their students, to government workers who feel that simply showing up to work is a heroic achievement, to executives and union workers in America’s oldest and least competitive industries.  If times are tough and money is tight, that means almost nothing is left over for productive investment.  What would have been a short recession will turn into a long depression and decades of higher taxes and slow growth to pay for all of the cash ladled out.  Special interest groups will continue to gain in power.

Practical Value

 

MARCH 17, 2009

Tale of Two Islands

David Henderson

Stanford University economists Peter Blair Henry and Conrad Miller recently published an interesting NBER Working Paper in which they compare economic policy and economic performance between Jamaica and Barbados.

Henry and Miller point out that in Jamaica, the People's National Party rose to power in the 1970s with the promise of "democratic socialism." Unfortunately, the PNP delivered, nationalizing companies, taxing trade, and imposing exchange controls. The PNP also distributed income through job-creation programs, schemes for housing development, and subsidies on food. Government spending rose from 23 percent of GDP in 1972 to 45 percent in 1978. The government financed much of its huge deficit by printing money, leading to 27 percent inflation by 1980.

The government of Barbados, by contrast, avoided nationalization and opened the country to trade. It also kept government spending under control although, unfortunately, Henry and Miller don't present data on government spending as a percent of GDP.

The economic results: between 1960 and 2002, real GDP per capita grew by an annual average of 2.2 percent in Barbados but only by 0.8 percent in Jamaica.

Henry and Miller pitch their study as a critique of the Douglass North view that institutions are crucial for economic growth. They point out that both countries were British colonies until the 1960s and, therefore, had a two-party political system, a free press, constitutional protection of property rights, and the English common law. The difference in performance, they say, was not due to different institutions but to different macro policy. But aren't such big differences in macro policy--nationalization and distribution of wealth in one case and not in the other--themselves a difference in institutions?

Update: Correction made, thanks to Bob.

CATEGORIES: Growth: Causal Factors , Institutional Economics , Macroeconomics

 

       What is Russia's GDP per capita?

Alex Tabarrok

Andrew Gelman has a simple question, What is Russia's GDP per capita?  Fortunately this information is easy to find on the web.  As Gelman reports, the answer is:

1.     $7,600 (World Bank 2007)

2.     $9,100 (World Bank 2007)

3.     $14,700 (PPP adjusted, World Bank 2007)

4.     $4,500 (World Bank 2006)

5.     $7600 or $14,400 (gross national income: "Atlas method" or "purchasing power parity," World Bank 2007)

6.     $12,600 (IMF 2008), $9,100 (World Bank 2007), or $12,500 (CIA 2008)

7.     $2,637 in 2000 US dollars (World Bank 2007); that's $3,200 in 2007 dollars

8.     $2,621 (World Bank 2006) or $8,600 (IMF)

Here are three lectures if you want to understand why this is a harder question than it appears!

 

 

IN DEFENSE OF TAX HAVENS
------------------------------------------------------------------------
 
A new form of "tax protectionism" is infecting Washington --    
several serious proposals are being floated in the nation's capital    
that would penalize Americans for investing in low-tax rather than    
high-tax jurisdictions says Richard W. Rahn, a senior fellow with the    
Cato Institute.
 
Proponents say the measures are needed to catch tax cheats -- but    
ignore the fact that most of the low-tax jurisdictions such as the    
Cayman Islands, Switzerland, etc., already have tax information    
exchange (for cases of probable cause), or tax withholding, agreements    
with the United States and other countries such as the United Kingdom    
and France.  Nevertheless, Sens. Carl Levin (D-Mich.), Bryon    
Dorgan (D-N.D.), and Max Baucus (D-Mont.), as well as officials of the    
Obama Treasury, want to make it more onerous and costly for American    
companies to do business around the world and for Americans to invest    
elsewhere.  They would even make it more difficult for    
non-Americans to invest in the United States, says Rahn:
 
   o   Levin's bill is a hodgepodge of tax increases, more    
       regulations and penalties on American taxpayers doing business    
       in targeted low-tax jurisdictions.
 
   o   Dorgan's bill would prevent certain American companies that    
       operate and are incorporated outside the United States from    
       being treated as nondomestic corporations, thus denying them    
       the right of tax deferral until their income is brought back    
       to the United States.
 
   o   Baucus, chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, is    
       circulating a draft bill that, among other things, would    
       extend the statute of limitations from three to six years for    
       tax returns reporting international transactions.
 
   o   The Treasury Department is proposing expanded regulations on    
       foreign financial institutions that bring needed investment    
       funds into the United States.
 
The so-called tax havens are for the most part no more than    
way-stations to temporarily collect savings from around the world until    
they are invested in productive projects, such as building a new    
shopping center or semi-conductor plant in the United States.     
This enables a better allocation of world capital, leading to higher,    
not lower, global growth rates, explains Rahn.
 
Indeed, to the extent tax competition between jurisdictions holds down    
the increase in the growth of governments, citizens of all countries    
experience more job opportunities and higher standards of living.     
And to the extent that businesses and individuals are discouraged by    
taxes or regulations from investing outside their own jurisdictions,    
they may simply choose to work and save less, period, says Rahn.
 
Source: Richard W. Rahn, "In Defense of Tax Havens," Wall    
Street Journal, March 18, 2009.
 
For text:
 
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123733986323064857.html 
 
 
For more on Taxes:      
 

Friedman and Sowell Dialogue on Bauer

Bryan Caplan

EMAIL CLEAR HIGHLIGHTS

Who's More Irresponsible?...

Prove Me Wrong: Vote Econlog!...

The latest issue of the Cato Journal features a transcript from a chat Milton Friedman and Thomas Sowell had about the late great Peter Bauer. Highlights:

Sowell: One of the things that [Bauer] mentioned in one of his later books was that people were saying things like: “We took all the rubber from Malaysia”; “We took all the tea from India.” And he pointed out that this was the direct opposite of the truth. The British brought the rubber tree to Malaysia; they brought the tea to India—and the Indians and Malaysians benefited.

[...]

Friedman: Many of these approaches [to economic development in the Third World] took on the characteristics of religion, which is believed without investigation. But yet, they must have been plausible. Large numbers of able people believed them. Those views were very deeply entrenched. So, it sounds simple to come along and say, “Look, obviously, if the vicious cycle of poverty were true, no country could have ever developed.” But, it wasn’t obvious at all and it took a good deal of courage and stubbornness to resist that trend.

Sowell: Because Peter Bauer wrote in such a very plain way, and because the things that he said now seem obvious, I fear that at some point in the future people will be looking back and say, “What was the big deal? All of this is just stuff anybody should have known.” But, it’s almost like saying, “So, the man traveled 10 miles in a day—what is that?” Until you say, “Well no, he traveled 10 miles hacking his way through a jungle,” and that’s essentially what Peter Bauer did. He had a whole jungle of preconceptions and dogmas out there.

Peter Bauer lived long enough to see cutting-edge development economists like Jeffrey Sachs endorse his main views. Unfortunately, he did not live long enough to criticize Sachs and company for their statist relapse.

CATEGORIES: Growth: Causal Factors

 

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5540

Does culture affect long-run growth?

Yuriy Gorodnichenko   Gérard Roland
21 September 2010

Print   Email
Comment   Republish

Does culture affect long-run growth? This column argues that countries with a more individualist culture have enjoyed higher long-run growth than countries with a more collectivist culture. Individualist culture attaches social status rewards to personal achievements and thus provides not only monetary incentives for innovation but also social status rewards.

 

The idea that culture is a central ingredient of economic development goes back to at least Max Weber who, in his classical work “The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism” (Weber 1905), argued that the protestant ethic of Calvinism was a very powerful force behind the development of capitalism in its early phases. In our new research (Gorodnichenko and Roland, 2010), we provide both a theoretical model and empirical evidence showing that countries with a more individualist culture have more innovation, a higher level of total factor productivity and higher long-run growth than countries with a more collectivist culture.

Here are the main tenets of our theoretical formulation of the idea:

In short, individualism better encourages innovation while collectivism has the advantage in coordinating production processes and in various forms of collective action.

To formalise the argument, we put these ingredients in an endogenous growth model to study the dynamic versus static elements of the trade-off. In the model, collectivism increases the overall efficiency in the economy, but these are static. Individualism meanwhile, spurs innovation and thus faster growth. Intuitively, people in an individualist culture have not only a monetary reward from innovation but also a social status reward. They are therefore willing, all other things being equal, to allocate more effort to innovative activities. The impact of this depends upon the overall setting.

This contrast can explain how countries with individualistic cultures were relatively backward before the Industrial Revolution, but overtook collectivist cultures afterwards. The model also yields an interesting relationship between culture and institutions. Under bad institutions, a predatory government can expropriate the monetary returns from innovation. However, social status and prestige cannot be expropriated. Therefore, even in societies where institutions are relatively predatory, there will be more innovation in an individualist culture because of the social status reward to innovation.

How do we bring these predictions to the data?

We use the individualism scores developed by Dutch sociologist Hofstede (2001).

Individuals in countries with a high level of the index value personal freedom and status, while individuals in countries with a low level of the index value harmony and conformity.

A broad array of survey questions is used to establish cultural values in different countries. Factor analysis is used to summarise the data and construct the individualism score. The latter is the first component in a principal component analysis and loads positively on valuing individual freedom, opportunity, achievement, advancement, recognition and negatively on valuing harmony, cooperation, relations with superiors. Hofstede’s measure of individualism has been validated in a number of studies. For example, across various studies and measures of individualism the UK, the US and the Netherlands are consistently among the most individualistic countries, while Pakistan, Nigeria and Peru are among the most collectivist.

We regress the log of GDP per worker on Hosftede’s individualism score and find a strong and significant positive effect of individualism (see Figure 1). The same is true if we use as dependent variables different measures of total factor productivity or measures of innovation (see Figure 2). According to our estimates, a one standard deviation increase in individualism score (say from the score of Venezuela to Greece, or from that of Brazil to Luxemburg) leads to an increase in the level of income of between 60% and 87% – a large effect. Figures 1 and 2 illustrate these relationships.

Figure 1. Individualism vs GDP per worker

Figure 2. Individualism vs patents per million

Ruling out other causes

The strong positive correlation between individualism on one hand and measures of long-run growth and innovation on the other hand can be due to a causal effect of culture on innovation and growth. One can also argue, however, that there might be a reverse causality at work; as countries get richer, their culture becomes more individualistic. In order to rule out reverse causality, we perform instrumental variable regression of growth and innovation on culture.

The instrumental variable we use is a measure of genetic distance between countries. In particular we employ a measure of the Euclidian distance between the frequency of blood types in a given country and the frequency of blood types in the US, which is the most individualistic country in our sample. These genetic data originate from Cavalli-Sforza et al. (1994), providing measures of genetic markers for roughly 2,000 groups of population across the globe.

Why can blood distance be a good instrumental variable?

The instrumental variable estimates of culture’s effect on long-run growth indicate a strong causal effect which is similar in magnitude to the effect implied by ordinary least squares regressions. These results are very robust to using other measures of genetic distance, blood distance to other countries, and other instrumental variables such as linguistic variables (e.g. languages that prohibit pronoun drops are more individualistic, see Kashima and Kashima 1998).

If we can exclude reverse causality, it might still be the case that blood distance affects long-run growth via other channels than individualism and collectivism. We rule out colonisation effects by showing that the effect of individualism on long-run growth still works when we exclude continents as the Americas and Oceania strongly affected by settler colonisation. The effect of individualism holds at the level of individual continents and even if we look only at European or OECD countries.

Other possible channels might be institutions, human capital, other measures of culture, and geographical distance. Indeed one can argue that these variables may be correlated with our measure of genetic distance. Even when we control for all these variables, we find that culture continues to have an important effect on income per capita and innovation. Other control variables we also use are measures of ethno-linguistic fractionalisation, legal origins, geographical controls such as distance from the equator or being landlocked. We find that generalised trust, a measure used in other research on culture, has no significant effect on long-run growth. In summary, we find that none of popular alternatives can undermine the strong causal effect of culture on economic outcomes.

Confirmation from cross-cultural psychology

The final confirmation for a causal effect of individualism on long run growth comes from recent advances in cross-cultural psychology which provide some direct evidence of genes’ effects on culture. We bring in three separate research strands.

Studies establishing these links emphasise that collectivism provides strong psychological support networks to deal with depression and stronger protection from social rejection. Similarly, more collectivist values emphasising tradition and putting stronger limits on individual behaviour, and showing less openness towards foreigners provide protection against disease spread. Using these three variables in turn as instruments, we find robust and significant effects of individualism on log output per worker with magnitudes similar to our baseline estimates.

We also find that institutions, measured by average protection against expropriation risk (the variable used in the famous work by Acemoglu et al. 2001 on the effect of institutions on long-run growth) can be explained by our individualism score but institutions also appear to affect culture. Culture and institutions, together with human capital, play a key role in explaining long-run growth.

What are the policy implications?

Understanding the effects of culture on economic development and economic performance is a fascinating task that the economics profession is only beginning to understand. Yet we advise caution when drawing policy conclusions from such analyses. Countries inherit their culture over a long historical period. It would be vain, and probably destructive, to try to impose cultural change on countries. On the contrary, countries need to embrace their cultural heritage and find institutions appropriate to this heritage. Cultural exchange is an integral part of the globalisation process and will no doubt benefit all as countries learn from the strengths and weaknesses of other countries’ culture in a spirit of tolerance, respect, and peace.

References

Acemoglu, D, S. Johnson, and J Robinson (2001), “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation”, American Economic Review, 91:1369-1401.

Gorodnichenko, Y and G Roland (2010), “Culture, Institutions and the Wealth of Nations”, CEPR Discussion Paper 8013

Kashima, E and Y Kashima (1998), “Culture and language: The case of cultural dimensions and personal pronoun use”, Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 29: 461-486.

Weber, Max (1905) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism.

 


This article may be reproduced with appropriate attribution. See Copyright (below).

The Demographics Driving Nations' Wealth

·         By DAVID WESSEL

Demography is not destiny. In 1300, China was bigger than Europe and had the world's most sophisticated technology. But China blew it. By 1850, its population was 65% larger than Europe's, but—thanks to the Industrial Revolution—Europeans were far richer.

Yet demography does matter. "We never pay enough attention to demography because it's so long term," says Dominique Strauss-Kahn, head of the International Monetary Fund. So turn for a moment from angst about the disappointing pace of the economic recovery and daunting government budget deficits, and look over the horizon.

 

Capital columnist David Wessel surveys the landscape over the next 40 years and makes some predictions about what the world's economies will look like.

Over the next 40 years, Japan and Europe will see working-age populations shrink by 30 million and 37 million, respectively, according to United Nations projections. Birth rates are low and so many of their people are already elderly.

China's working-age population will keep growing for 15 years or so, then turn down, the result of its one-child policy and the tendency of birth rates to fall as incomes rise. In 2050, the U.N. projects, China will have 100 million fewer workers than it does today. India's population, in contrast, will grow by 300 million working-age persons over the next 40 years.

The U.S. is in between, benefiting from a higher birth rate and younger populations than Europe and Japan and more immigration. It is projected to add 35 million working-age persons by 2050.

So what?

History, as interpreted by modern economists pondering the mysteries of growth, teaches that more people lead to more ideas. And unlike land or oil, ideas can be used by more than one person simultaneously. Before countries began sharing ideas, the biggest had the most rapid technological progress. Now, trade, travel and the Internet speed new ideas around the globe ever-more rapidly. So the benefits are dispersed. Belgium is rich not because it is big or has invented a lot, but because it has the wherewithal to employ technology invented by others, notes Michael Kremer of Harvard University. Zaire is bigger, but lacks the wherewithal.

"In the coming decades, because of the Internet, because of many other changes that have shrunk the world, it's almost impossible for an individual country to keep proprietary technology for itself," says Mr. Strauss-Kahn. For a time, relatively small countries like Britain and France were global heavyweights because of their technological prowess. That day is over, he predicts. "Power equals numbers," he reasons, and that leads him to anticipate the rising influence of China and India.

Rising populations—and growing numbers of meat-eating, oil-burning consumers—create tension between environmental costs and idea-generating benefits. Some worry about the costs; others see the benefits.

"China's population is roughly equal to that of the U.S., Europe and Japan combined," optimistic Stanford University economists Chad Jones and Paul Romer observed recently in an academic journal. "Over the next several decades, the continued economic development of China might plausibly double the number of researchers throughout the world pushing forward the technological frontier. What effect will this have on incomes in countries that share ideas with China in the long run?" Somewhere between a lot and really a lot, they say. In fact, they say that even if the U.S. had to bear all the costs of mitigating the added carbon emitted by a rapidly developing China, ideas generated by the Chinese would boost U.S. per capita income enough to more than compensate.

Despite the Internet, multinational companies and global financial markets, we are not—yet—one big world economy. Divergences in demographics have national consequences.

View Full Image

 

ZUMApress.com

A worker checks a train wheel on a production line Wednesday at Maanshan Iron & Steel Co. in China's Anhui Province.

 

Today, one in five Japanese and Europeans is over age 65. In 2050, it will be one in three. Rapid productivity growth—the amount of stuff produced per hour of work—could make it easier for working-age populations to support the old folks, but productivity trends aren't promising. The Japanese and Europeans almost surely will have to work longer, take fewer vacations and probably pay more taxes. Aging also threatens the Japanese government's ability to keep borrowing so heavily. IMF economist Kiichi Tokuoka estimates that at least half of Japanese government borrowing is now financed, directly or indirectly, by Japanese households; unlike the U.S., Japan doesn't borrow heavily from abroad. Japanese savers will be selling bonds in retirement—and there aren't enough younger workers to save enough to pick up the slack.

For China, the challenge is to build social structures and retirement schemes to sustain a growing cadre of old folks that, unlike previous generations, won't be able to rely so much on its children for support. Today, 1.4% of Chinese are over age 80; in 2050, 7.2% will be, the U.N. projects.

Related Links

India has more time to adjust since its working population is likely to keep growing. Its challenge is to harness the growing number of workers in their 30s and 40s and to nurture industry and services. If India dismantles archaic labor laws, brings more women into the work force and invests in training and education, demographics could add four percentage points a year to economic growth, Goldman Sachs economists estimate. But that's a big "if."

And the U.S.? For all today's gloom, it may be in the sweet spot. A growing population, an openness to ambitious immigrants and trade (if not disrupted by xenophobic politics) and strong productivity growth (if sustained) could lift living standards and bring faster growth, which would reduce big government budget deficits far easier for the U.S. than for slower growing Europe and Japan.

Write to David Wessel at capital@wsj.com

 

Does Economic Success Require Democracy?



From the May/June 2007 Issue

Filed under: World Watch, Economic Policy, Government and Politics

Sadly, no. In fact, the politically unfree countries are enjoying more economic growth than the politically free ones. Kevin Hassett tells why.

When Kenneth Arrow was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1972, one of the contributions the awards committee cited was his miraculous “impossibility” theorem. Decades from now, Arrow’s theorem, originally drawn in his doctoral dissertation, will be viewed as the 20th-century idea that best anticipated the 21st century.

While mathematical in origin, the impossibil­ity theorem is simple to describe in words:

A government is really just a mechanism that makes collective decisions for a large number of cit­izens who have different preferences. I might want to spend our tax dollars on dog parks; you might prefer more police. The government’s job is to work it out. This job is called “aggregating preferences.” In the U.S., we send signals with voting to help the government aggregate preferences.

Dictatorships now understand that they have to provide a good economy to keep citizens happy, and they understand that free-market econ­omies work best.

Arrow was able to show that no voting scheme can be devised that will create a government that has rational preferences, where rationality is defined precisely by Arrow as meeting a number of condi­tions. Democracy might be a form of government that many prefer to live under, but there is nothing theoretically compelling that suggests that it is the form of government that best reflects the underly­ing preferences of citizens. As a result, democracies will not necessarily outperform other types of mech­anisms for preference aggregation as a route to economic prosperity. Democracies will not always win.

In the latter half of the 20th century, this obser­vation seemed irrelevant. The United States, with its free markets and democracy, defeated the Soviet Union, with its centrally planned economy and party dictatorship.

But in the 21st century, things look different. Dictatorships, as in China, appear to have learned from the failure of the Soviets. While they continue to oppress political opponents, they allow a high level of economic freedom within their borders.

So far, this approach is working, and in a big way—as the chart illustrates. An organization called Freedom House rates the level of political freedom of the world’s nations on a scale of 1 to 7, with 1 the most free. For example, according to the 2006 sur­vey, countries like the United States and Italy are rated 1, while Singapore is rated 4.5, China and Saudi Arabia 6.5, and North Korea 7. In addition, the Fraser Institute in Canada rates the economic freedom of nations, looking at taxes, regulation, trade barriers, and the like.

The chart shows the economic growth of two different sets of countries. The first set comprises nations that are both politically and economically free; the second, those that are repressed politically (have high numbers on the Freedom House scale) but are economically free. In each case, I looked at the average five-year growth rate of GDP, weighted by the size of each respective economy.

The chart tells a striking story: the countries that are economically and politically free are underper­forming the countries that are economically but not politically free. For example, unfree China had a growth rate of 9.5 percent from 2001 to 2005. But China was not the whole story—Malaysia’s GDP grew 9.5 percent from 1991 to 1995, Singapore’s GDP grew 6.4 percent from 1996 to 2000, and Russia’s grew 6.1 percent from 2001 to 2005.

The unfree governments now understand that they have to provide a good economy to keep citizens happy, and they understand that free-market econ­omies work best. Also, nearly all of the unfree nations are developing countries. History shows they grow faster, at least for a while, than mature nations. But being unfree may be an economic advantage. Dictatorships are not hamstrung by the preferences of voters for, say, a pervasive welfare state.

So the future may look something like the 20th century in reverse. The unfree nations will grow so quickly that they will overwhelm free nations with their economic might. The unfree will see no reason to transition to democracy.

Meanwhile, democracies may copy many of the market-friendly policies of the dictatorships, but it seems unlikely that free citizens will choose to reduce their own political freedoms.

Democracies will stay in the game, but, as Arrow showed long ago, their victory is not assured.

Kevin Hassett is director of economic policy studies at the American Enterprise Institute

 

 

Spain's jobless rate surges to 20.33%

by Katell Abiven Katell Abiven – 1 hr 23 mins ago Jan 28,2011

MADRID (AFP) – Spain announced Friday its jobless rate surged to a 13-year record above 20 percent at the end of 2010, the highest level in the industrialized world, as the economy struggled for air.

It was more bad news for an economy fighting to regain the trust of financial markets and avoid being trapped in a debt quagmire that has engulfed Greece and Ireland and now menaces Portugal.

Another 121,900 people joined Spain's unemployment queues in the final quarter of the year, pushing the total to 4.697 million people, said the national statistics institute INE.

The resulting unemployment rate was 20.33 percent for the end of the year -- easily exceeding Prime Minister Jose Luis Rodriguez Zapatero's target of 19.4 percent.

Spain appears to be stuck in a rut of staggeringly high levels of unemployment.

After posting a jobless rate of 18.83 percent in 2009 and now 20.33 percent in 2010, the government is forecasting 19.3 percent for 2011 and 17.5 percent in 2012.

The Spanish economy, the European Union's fifth biggest, slumped into recession during the second half of 2008 as the global financial meltdown compounded the collapse of a labour-intensive construction boom

It emerged with tepid growth of just 0.1 percent in the first quarter of 2010 and 0.2 percent in the second but then stalled with zero growth in the third.

Zapatero has said the fourth quarter will show positive growth which would pick up steam in 2011 but he warned that job creation would be "far from what we need and desire. It will be slow and progressive."

Last month the government announced it was scrapping a 426-euro ($568) monthly subsidy for the long-term unemployed so as to slash the public deficit and ease fears that it will need an EU bailout.

The government forecasts a 0.3-percent drop in growth this year will be followed by an expansion of 1.3 percent in 2011.

Madrid estimates 70 percent of the two million jobs which were lost in Spain since the start of the economic downturn were directly or indirectly related to the construction sector.

Last year the government introduced a hotly contested labour market reform that cut the country's high cost of firing workers and gave companies more flexibility to reduce working hours and staff levels in economic downturns -- changes that he argued would boost job creation.

Spaniards see unemployment as Spain's biggest problem and one in two, 49.8 percent, fear the jobless situation will get worse, a poll published by the CIS research firm this month showed.

 

A Two-Track Plan to Restore Growth

Our economic wounds are self-inflicted. Changing fiscal and monetary policies could make a difference fast.

By JOHN B. TAYLOR

It's been three years since the financial crisis flared up and the recession began. Yet the unemployment rate is still over 9%—double what it was before the recession—and it's been stuck above 9% for 20 consecutive months. Why the extraordinarily high and prolonged unemployment? My research shows that discretionary government interventions—deviations from sound economic principles and policies—have been largely responsible.

Many government interventions occurred before the panic in the fall of 2008, but in the past two years the government doubled down. We have seen an $862 billion stimulus, an increase in federal spending to 25% from 21% of GDP, and a corresponding explosion of federal debt. We have the Fed's unconventional "quantitative easings": purchases of $1.25 trillion of mortgage backed securities and $900 billion of longer-term Treasury bonds. And we have seen hundreds of new regulations in the health and financial sectors.

The one-time stimulus payments to people did not jump-start consumption. The stimulus grants to states did not increase infrastructure spending. Cash for clunkers merely shifted consumption a few months forward. The Fed's purchases did not have a material impact on mortgage interest rates once changes in risks are taken into account. At best these actions had a small temporary effect that dissipated quickly, leaving a legacy of higher debt, a bloated Fed balance sheet and uncertainty—all of which slow growth and job creation.

None of this should be surprising. Well-known theories of consumption predict that temporary payments to households will not increase economic growth by much. Careful empirical studies of stimulus programs in the 1970s showed that stimulus grants to states did not increase infrastructure spending. A vast literature and experience from the 1970s show that discretionary monetary policy, as distinct from rules-based policy, leads to boom-bust cycles with ultimately higher unemployment and higher inflation. With sounder, more stable and more predictable monetary and fiscal policies in the 1980s and '90s we had long expansions and lower unemployment.

The best way to reduce unemployment is to restore sound fiscal and monetary policies. There are some welcome signs that the policy pendulum has begun to swing back in that direction. The recent election revealed deep concern about high debt, deficits and spending.

Three-fourths of business economists and one-half of academic economists say that easy monetary policy exacerbated the housing boom and bust that led to the financial crisis. Reactions to a second round of quantitative easing have been negative at home and abroad. The very word "stimulus" is now avoided by former proponents of spending stimulus. The recent agreement to extend existing income tax rates represents a shift to more predictable policies.

Unfortunately, the president's State of the Union speech raised doubts about the return to sound policy by stressing more government spending and criticizing further extensions of current personal income tax rates. So it is essential for policy makers to grab the policy pendulum, pull it back toward sound fiscal and monetary policy, and tie it in place so it never swings back again.

They should start by laying out a credible plan to reduce spending and stop the debt explosion. If spending as a share of GDP can be brought to 2000 levels and held there with entitlement reforms, then the budget can be balanced without employment-retarding tax-rate increases. A concrete goal should be to establish a long-term budget that the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) can credibly show would bring the debt-to-GDP ratio to 40%. If the plan is ready for this summer's CBO long-term projections, it will give an immediate boost to economic growth and job creation as uncertainty about debt sustainability falls. An example of what the CBO's next projection might look like is shown in the nearby chart of U.S. debt history along with the CBO's projections made in 2009, 2010 and, if the plan is ready, in 2011.

Some want to delay reducing government spending because of high unemployment and the fragile recovery. But there is no convincing evidence that a gradual and credible reduction in government purchases will increase unemployment. The history of the past two decades shows that lower government purchases as a share of GDP are associated with lower unemployment rates. A much better way to reduce unemployment is to encourage private investment. Over the past two decades, unemployment fell when investment increased as a share of GDP. (See the other nearby chart.)

Meanwhile, the Fed should lay out a plan for reducing its extraordinarily large balance sheet. To achieve a more predictable rules-based policy going forward, the Fed's objectives should be clarified. The Federal Reserve Act now says the Fed must "promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates." But too many goals blur responsibility and accountability and they allow for confusing changes in emphasis from one goal to another.

Recently the multiple objectives have been used as a rationale for interventionist policies, such as QE2, an approach that Fed officials avoided in the 1980s and '90s. Such interventions can have the unintended consequence of increasing unemployment—as illustrated by the decisions to hold interest rates very low in 2003-2005, which may have caused a bubble and led to the high unemployment today.

It would be better for economic growth and job creation if the Fed's objective was simply "long-run price stability within a clear framework of economic stability." Such a goal would provide a foundation for strong employment growth and would not prevent the Fed from providing liquidity, serving as lender of last resort, and cutting the interest rate in a financial crisis or recession.

The Fed should also be required to report in writing and in hearings its strategy for monetary policy. Such a requirement was removed by Congress in 2000 and should be restored. But rather than reporting only on the monetary aggregates as in the past, the renewed requirement should focus on the strategy for setting interest rates. The Fed should establish its own strategy and report it to Congress.

The Fed would have the discretion to deviate from its strategy in a crisis. But if it does deviate it should be required to report the reasons. This approach provides a degree of political control and accountability appropriate for an independent agency without interfering in day-to-day operations. Such reforms will reverse the short-term focus of policy and help achieve sustained growth and job creation.

Mr. Taylor, a professor of economics at Stanford and a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, is the author of "Getting Off Track: How Government Actions and Interventions Caused, Prolonged and Worsened the Financial Crisis" (Hoover Press, 2009). This op-ed was adapted from his testimony before the House Committee on Financial Services this week.

 

A New Hanseatic League

Dutch Prime Minister Mark Rutte is recruiting for a European free-trade zone.

Starting from the 13th century, and continuing for some 300 years, the Hanseatic League guaranteed free trade for its merchant members across a huge swath of Northern Europe. Now Dutch Prime Minister Mark Rutte has an idea for a free-trade block within the EU that would revive the best features of the Hansa of old. Europe's lagging economies could use a boost, and Mr. Rutte's inspiration is to liberalize the services market, which accounts for more than two-thirds of European commerce. What's more, the Dutch premier doesn't feel like waiting for those EU members who still aren't ready.

In 2006 tales of dirt-cheap Polish plumbers helped stoke enough fear in Western Europe to scupper the EU's Services Directive, which would have let service providers operate freely across national borders. By 2010, employers in Austria, Germany, Belgium, France and Poland, told Manpower Inc. that their top hiring challenge was a shortage of skilled tradesmen—these include welders, electricians, and, yes, plumbers.

This week Mr. Rutte declared his intention to revive the Services Directive, even if he can only get a few of his EU partners on board. He told Britain's Guardian that he wants "to form a mini-single market for all the professional services, and then obviously the hope is that all 27 countries would like to join, even if some are currently vehemently opposed." Mr. Rutte has already discussed his plan with British Prime Minister David Cameron, and plans to approach other self-avowed European free marketeers, saying he is "absolutely convinced the Scandics, the Baltics and other countries will be willing" to consider it.

View Full Image

 

ullstein bild / The Granger Collection

Sixteenth century Lübeck, Germany.

The original European common market dates back to the 13th century, when the Hanseatic League formed in the northern German city of Lübeck and expanded across Europe's North and Baltic Sea regions. The armed union of merchants together tackled trade barriers from tolls to pirates to overlords, and worked well at least for the early part of its history. Today's proposed revival would presumably refrain from sacking jurisdictions that refuse its members monopoly rights or free passage—a bonus for the likes of modern Germany, which, among other hassles, requires work permits from all eastern European workers.

A Downing Street official tells us that Mr. Rutte's suggestion "isn't something we've taken a view on yet." Getting behind any EU initiative is politically risky in Britain, but ultimately freer trade with Europe would mean a pro-growth win that wouldn't cost Mr. Cameron's cash-strapped government a penny. Of the Baltic and Scandinavian governments who responded to our queries, Latvia was the most enthusiastic, saying that while "in principle we do not think a two-speed Europe is desirable, we could look into the possibility of enhanced cooperation in the services sector if approached." The rest were more guarded, saying they wanted to avoid "fragmenting the internal market."

Except there is no internal market to speak of today for European services. And attractive as 27-nation unity is, the EU does allow as few as nine countries to work on initiatives separately from the rest. So far though, "enhanced cooperation" has been eyed mostly by France and Germany as a means of exerting economic control over other Europeans.

Mr. Rutte's proposal, by contrast, would increase opportunities in all participating countries, both for individuals and businesses. If Tallinn or London, or Stockholm or Riga or Vilnius, are nervous that Mr. Rutte's idea would meet resistance from Paris and Berlin, they might have a point. But Mr. Rutte's suggestion is a welcome chance for Europe's free traders to take the lead. If the Continent's protectionists want to be left behind, it would be their loss.

Printed in The Wall Street Journal, page 12

 

Downgrading Japan

A big economy is no protection from the consequences of bad fiscal policies.

Speaking of fiscal train wrecks (see above), Standard & Poor's yesterday downgraded Japan's sovereign debt by one notch, to AA- from AA. We're the last people to view a rating firm's diktats as definitive on anything, nor will this one come as much of a surprise to anyone who's been following Tokyo's spending habits. But it is still suggestive, and usefully timed to coincide with important debates unfolding in Washington.

The main lesson of which S&P has reminded everyone is that no government should assume it is immune from fiscal realities simply by virtue of sitting atop a large economy. Japan is the third-largest economy in the world, and the second-largest among developed countries behind the U.S. Yet thanks to two decades of sluggish growth combined with out-of-control spending, the ratio of government debt to GDP is now, at around 200%, the highest anywhere. The expectation of more spending and higher debt prompted S&P's move.

View Full Image

 

Associated Press

Naoto Kan

 

The drivers of such outlays will sound eerily familiar: pension spending at about 30% of the budget and rising due to an aging population; projected failure to reduce annual budget deficits (owing to mounting social spending); and what S&P describes as the ruling Democratic Party of Japan's "lack [of] a coherent strategy to address these negative aspects of the country's debt dynamics."

S&P—and plenty of others—err mainly when they imply that tax hikes such as Japan's oft-discussed increase in the consumption tax are a viable way to fix these problems. Japan has reached this pass despite having the highest corporate tax rates in the developed world. Tokyo would be far better off pursuing growth-boosting reforms.

Those atwitter about an imminent debtpocalypse will be disappointed. Japan is fortunate to be a net external creditor (unlike, say, Greece). So there's no obvious trigger for a Europe-style panic so long as domestic investors continue in their willingness to buy Tokyo's bonds, which they show every sign of doing, for now at least. S&P's analysis should be read instead as a longer-term reminder that when it comes to dysfunctional fiscs, things can't go on forever as they have, even in a large economy. Come to think of it, that's a message some in Washington need to hear, too.

Printed in The Wall Street Journal, page 9

 

 

 

Feeling the Heat: Comparing Global Inflation

Consumer prices are moving unevenly across the world. Economic growth, supply and demand, currency values and a variety of other factors drive consumer prices up — inflation — or down — deflation. The following graphic gives a snapshot of inflation rates in 50 of 51 largest economies. (The U.A.E is excluded because it doesn’t have consistent data for the full period.)

Asia's Bond Market Comes Alive

In the coming decade the region will surpass Europe and rival the U.S.

By SOOFIAN J. ZUBERI

For years, East Asia's lack of viable bond markets and its companies' consequent reliance on bank lending sparked concern about the region's financial stability. But in the past few years bond issuance has accelerated dramatically. From 2000-2010, Asian credit market issuance as a share of global issuance has grown to 23% from 5%, the result of an annual growth rate of 27%.

The benefits of growing Asian bond markets are many. Risk is priced more transparently and efficiently, and systemic risk is reduced. A vibrant bond market is a means of tapping into long-term savings and maintaining high levels of liquidity while increasing capital available to companies in a high-growth region.

In 2010, Asian issuers raised a staggering $2.8 trillion via the bond markets—3.3 times the amount raised in the equity markets. The largest Asian nonsovereign credit deal was a $4.4 billion bond by Chinese electric utility State Grid. The market also absorbed perpetual bonds by blue chip names like the Hong Kong conglomerate Hutchison.

At the same time, local currency markets are growing. Last month, Chinese real estate company Evergrande raised $1.4 billion in a yuan-denominated international bond issue. In December 2010 alone, investors, predominantly foreign funds, bought more than $1 billion of Thai debt in the secondary markets. This means local markets are rapidly achieving critical mass.

This is just the beginning of an explosive boom in Asian credit. In the coming decade, the region will exceed Europe and rival the U.S. as a credit-issuance market.

This growth will be driven by demand- and supply-side factors. First is the strong demand among Asian companies for more capital to fuel growth. Given the region's demographics and higher growth rates, Asian companies will continue to look to leverage the capital markets to fund growth, capacity expansion and mergers and acquisitions.

The second factor will be improving Asian sovereign credit profiles. As the ratings agencies downgrade European sovereigns and U.S. municipal bonds, Asia is the one bright spot for credit upgrades. This continues a multiyear theme of Asian upgrades following the 1998 Asian financial crisis, and one would expect countries such as Indonesia to join India, Korea and China as investment-grade issuers. These ratings upgrades would naturally benefit banks through greater credit lines and simultaneously enable more global institutional investors to focus on Asian companies.

Asian firms deleveraged dramatically after the Asian financial crisis. Add to this that there are more than 1,000 Asian companies with a market capitalization above $1 billion—more than in the U.S.—and conditions are ripe for large bond issues.

Asia has also developed wider and deeper investor pools. Asian credit is less than 2% of the holdings of most of the large global pension funds and insurance companies. Growing numbers of U.S. and European institutional investors are setting up Asian credit funds and opening offices in Hong Kong and Singapore. Developed-market insurance companies are steadily increasing their Asian allocations. Top-tier companies will benefit from Asian central banks diversifying their growing reserves away from U.S. Treasurys and developed-market blue chip bonds.

Moreover, as Asian governments encourage pension-fund growth and the average Asia consumer demographic starts to migrate from 20-year-olds entering the work force to increased numbers of savers, demand will increase for longer-dated credit products. Classic pension-fund success stories include NPS of Korea and EPF of Malaysia, both of which are increasingly focusing on credit as an asset class.

Regional banks will play an important role in developing bond markets, and their balance sheets are growing. Including HSBC, five of the world's top 10 banks by market capitalization are now Asian. Asian companies are key beneficiaries of the growing trend of Chinese banks building offshore Asian branch networks. Other non-Asian global financial institutions such as Bank of America Merrill Lynch and Citigroup are focused on growing their Asian balance sheets.

The final factor is product innovation and market reforms. Asian companies can now borrow in other Asian currencies. Investors benefit from the positive trends of underlying Asian foreign-exchange appreciation, diversification and local currency yields, while issuers seek lowest-cost funding bases, as well as investor and funding-source diversification.

Perhaps the biggest trend will be the ability of Asian and global multinational corporations to fund in yuan as a result of the Chinese government's approach to prudently liberalizing its currency regime, thereby providing opportunities for companies with onshore operations to fund these in the local currency.

While there will be volatility and periods of corrections, these forces—and others unforeseen—will combine to unleash a revolution in Asian credit markets. Issuers and investors will benefit alike.

Mr. Zuberi is head of Asia- Pacific global markets distribution at Bank of America Merrill Lynch

 

China Starts Trial Property Tax to Cool Market

By ESTHER FUNG

SHANGHAI—China announced details of a long-awaited property tax in two of its largest urban centers, but the move intended to crack down on speculation and curb rising prices that are fueling public anger was relatively mild and analysts said it would have only a limited impact on investment.

View Full Image

 

Bloomberg News

Workers at the site of a residential development in Chongqing, China, this week. The city is levying a tax on villas and some second homes.

 

The trial tax, the closest thing yet to the style of tax levied annually on residential property in countries like the U.S., will be applied differently in Chongqing and Shanghai, apparently to see which one works best, before being rolled out across the country.

The tax comes after the country's cabinet on Wednesday raised the minimum down payment on second-home purchases to 60% from 50%, and imposed limits on home purchases as part of efforts to cool the overheated real-estate sector and rein in inflation.

"The tax, by itself, is not very harsh," said Remy Chan, managing director of CBD Commercial Investment Management, a 3 billion yuan ($456 billion) private-equity property fund in Shanghai. "But together with the new limits on home purchases and higher down payment for second homes, it shows the government is determined to rein in speculation."

The tax, which comes into effect Friday, "can guide residents toward more rational housing consumption" and "promote social equality," the Ministry of Finance said Thursday in a statement issued jointly with the Ministry of Housing and Urban-Rural Development and the State Administration of Taxation.

"Levying property tax on residential housing can help reasonably adjust income allocation and promote social equality," the statement added. It will be expanded to other cities "when the time is ripe" it said, without giving a timetable.

Late last month, Premier Wen Jiabao said the property-cooling measures announced so far hadn't been implemented well enough and prices had yet to meet his expectations. Property prices rose 0.3% in December from the previous month, and 6.4% from a year earlier. Property prices slowed for the eight months to December on an annualized basis.

Chongqing Mayor Huang Qifan said the city would levy a real-estate tax on villas owned by individuals—usually luxury, stand-alone homes—and on newly purchased high-end homes at three rates: 0.5%, 1%, and 1.2%, depending on market transaction prices.

Three to five years after a purchase, the tax may be based on the appraised value of the property, he said. In addition, the city will levy a tax on second homes newly bought by non-Chongqing residents who don't own companies or aren't employed by any company in the city, a move that apparently targets speculators.

Separately, the Shanghai government said it would levy a temporary 0.6% real-estate tax on homes and may cut the rate to 0.4% for properties whose transaction prices are below certain—unspecified—levels.

A statement by Shanghai's housing department said the tax would apply to second homes newly bought by Shanghai-resident families or to first homes newly bought by nonresident families.

"It's a mild plan overall, and the primary impact will be psychological rather than economic," said Michael Klibaner, head of research at Jones Lang LaSalle China,."We finally have some clarity. It's a surprise that the tax will be in effect tomorrow, but the tax rate came in line or slightly lower than the recent rumors," Mr. Klibaner said. He said it seemed the aim was to support end-user demand, but it likely will have a limited impact on investment demand, as the tax is lower than the investment yield of about 2% in Shanghai. The progressive tax in Chongqing and flat tax in Shanghaitaxes show that the government wants to experiment before rolling out a real-estate tax to other cities, he said.

One of the intentions of the tax is to provide a recurring source of income for local governments to reduce their reliance on income from land sales, which encourages high prices.

Both cities said the tax revenue would be used to support public-housing construction. However, Mr. Huang, the Chongqing mayor, said the trial tax "carries more symbolic significance" in reforming people's consumption habits and promoting better income allocation, and may not generate much fiscal revenue in the near term.

He estimated that the tax could bring in around 150 million yuan of fiscal revenue this year, only a fraction of the 100 billion yuan that the city needs to invest in public housing construction over the next three years.

He also played down public expectations about the short-term impact of the tax, saying it can only curb speculation and property prices "to some extent".

"Maintaining a good local property-market order isn't something that can be achieved overnight. Rather, it's a complicated project," he said. "Nobody believes that the real-estate tax can hit the Achilles' heel" immediately by pushing down property prices, he said.

Analysts have said that if the tax doesn't push down housing prices, it will lead to even more public resentment. Some also raise the possibility of more rampant speculation in cities that have yet to be included in the trial program.

The government currently charges a 1.2% annual tax on 70%-90% of the value of commercial properties. The commercial real-estate tax is largely based on the cost of developing properties, excluding the cost of the land, industry observers have said.

China introduced a series of measures last year to rein in property-price rises, including limiting home purchases, raising down-payment requirements and twice raising interest rates. Analysts say a real-estate tax could help stabilize the market.

—Victoria Ruan contributed to this article.

 

 ****************r4

 

WSJ  Econ Blog Jan 31, 2011
5:00 AM

The Great Stagnation, Low-Hanging Fruit and America’s ‘Sputnik Moment’

By Kelly Evans

Few people outside a small niche of economists and intellectuals took notice at the time, but a potentially important event quietly took place last week: the publication on Tuesday of Tyler Cowen’s concise treatise — as a $4 Kindle e-book, no less — called “The Great Stagnation: How America Ate All The Low-Hanging Fruit of Modern History, Got Sick, and Will (Eventually) Feel Better.”

Mr. Cowen is a libertarian-leaning economist at George Mason University and a columnist for The New York Times, but he is best-known for the sharp, thoughtful blog called “Marginal Revolution” that he and colleague Alex Tabarrok have been keeping since 2003.

This isn’t Mr. Cowen’s first book, but it is probably his most important — or at least, his most impactful — one. It’s not that he has the final say on America’s current economic malaise, but rather because he takes the debate in an entirely new direction (new, at least, to most people) that gives so much value to his work. His assessment may be bleak, but it is honest. His arguments aren’t perfect, and “low-hanging fruit” doesn’t quite have the catchiness of “The World is Flat,” but in terms of framing the dialogue Tyler Cowen may very well turn out to be this decade’s Thomas Friedman.

His essential point is that economic development and technological innovation have reached a plateau, and unfortunately we in America are only now just realizing it: “Political discourse and behavior have become highly polarized, and what I like to call the ‘honest middle’ cannot be heard above the din. People often blame the economic policies of ‘the other side’ or they belligerently snipe at foreign competition. But we are failing to understand why we are failing. All of these problems have a single, little-noticed root cause: We have been living off low-hanging fruit for at least three hundred years. We have built social and economic institutions on the expectation of a lot of low-hanging fruit, but that fruit is mostly gone.”

What does he mean by low-hanging fruit? He lists three major forms — free land, technological breakthroughs (specifically during the 1880-1940 period), and smart, uneducated kids — and two minor ones, cheap fossil fuels and the U.S. Constitution. In other words, these preconditions gave rise to rapid growth and incredible prosperity over the last couple of centuries, but we have now exhausted their dividends. The most obvious measure of this is the stagnation of median household wages in the U.S. for several decades now. “If median income had continued to grow at its earlier postwar rate, the median family income today would be over $90,000,” he notes — about 50% higher than where it currently is.

His proposed solution, “Raise the social status of scientists,” feels a bit empty after his elegant appraisal of our challenges, and doesn’t, for example, explain how doing so might fix a critical problem he earlier singles out: that “A lot of our recent innovations are ‘private goods’…that benefit some individuals but are not public goods more generally.” (Think, for instance, of recent innovation in the financial sector compared with past innovation that led to railroads, highways and penicillin.)

But again, perhaps most important is the way in which he is shifting and framing the debate. The rest of the econoblogosphere is already abuzz with its own observations or proscriptions for this new era of societal development, whatever its ultimate form may be. Recent efforts to replace gross domestic product measures with something more like Bhutan’s gross national happiness gauge (supporting by Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz and French President Nicholas Sarkozy, among others) are just one effect of this paradigm shift. Economists are now looking for “soft” measures that better capture wellbeing to replace or at least complement the old, “hard” measures that only capture earnings and output.

A particular challenge we confront is that our progress as a society — chiefly, in extending and improving lives — is now at a point in which it appears to be undercutting our potential for further advancement. Part of this, Mr. Cowen observes, stems from well-meaning efforts to do more with education, government, and health care that instead seem to have backfired and left us with noncompetitive institutions closer to failing us than to serving us well.

Mr. Cowen’s book would be a more invigorating read if it weren’t so sobering. He is no Cassandra — he allows that we may reap another harvest of low-hanging fruit from the Internet, for example, but points out that the services it offers, however valuable, don’t generate a lot of revenue. What is exciting, however, is to imagine students, economists, and scientists across the country reading the book, coming to terms with the depth of our challenge and pursuing new ways of trying to “fix” things or generally improve our lot. President Obama, in his State of the Union address, called for a new “Sputnik moment” in the U.S. — but offered little idea of what he meant by that. Mr. Cowen gives us a much better sense of what we should collectively be working towards — and what is at stake if we fail.

WSJ  Econ Blog Jan 29, 2011
5:00 AM

Number of the Week: Banks Should Hold More Capital

By Mark Whitehouse

Number of the Week

52%

52%: Optimal bank capital-to-assets ratio, according to a new study.

Not long ago, U.S. Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner summed up what is required to protect the global financial system from another disaster in three words: “Capital, capital, capital.” Contrary to bankers’ protestations, a growing body of research suggests that the world would be much better off if banks had a lot more of it.

Bankers typically present capital requirements as a sort of zero-sum game, or worse. If banks have more capital — that is, finance their activities with more of their own shareholders’ money, or equity, as opposed to debt — they’ll be less likely to go bankrupt and exacerbate crises. But, the logic goes, capital is expensive: If they can’t use as much cheap, borrowed money, banks will have to charge more for loans, an outcome that could hobble the economy and make us all poorer.

That logic, though, contradicts an insight that financial economists Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller had more than 50 years ago: Any firm’s financing costs shouldn’t depend on the mix of debt and equity it chooses. Shareholders demand high returns on bank equity in part because banks’ heavy borrowing subjects them to a lot of risk. Many banks typically borrow $30 or more for every $1 their shareholders put in, so a mere 3% drop in the value of their assets can wipe out the shareholders’ investment completely. If banks borrowed less, equity would probably be cheaper. The only reason debt remains a better deal is that governments subsidize it through creditor bailouts and tax breaks on interest.

More importantly, the potential benefits of having safer banks are immense. In  a new paper, three Bank of England economists — led by David Miles, formerly of Morgan Stanley — conclude that the benefits far outweigh the costs. Their work builds on an earlier Bank for International Settlements  study, which this column touched on last year.

The Bank of England economists estimate, for example, that a permanent one-percentage-point reduction in the probability of banking crises is worth more than half an entire year’s economic output. By contrast, permanently doubling banks’ capital ratios would add only about 0.06 percentage point to companies’ financing costs, taking a long-term bite out of the economy equivalent to about 6% of one year’s output.

The upshot: If one assumes that really bad crises tend to happen every few decades or so, the most beneficial capital level would be 52% of assets, weighted according to their riskiness. Even if one assumes the future holds only mediocre crises, the optimal capital ratio would be about 19%. That compares to a 7% requirement big global banks must meet by 2019 under new rules drawn up in Basel last year.

  • WSJ JANUARY 31, 2011

The Economic Roots Of the Revolt

Few countries have been less integrated into the global economy than Egypt.

By ZACHARY KARABELL

The mass movement engulfing Egypt exposes a fact that has been hiding in plain sight: In a decade during which China has brought more people out of poverty at a faster rate than ever in human history, in a period of time where economic reform has been sweeping the world from Brazil to Indonesia, Egypt has missed out.

A decade ago, IBM ran a series of commercials featuring its global reach. One included a fisherman sailing on the Nile, tapping into a wireless network. It was an enticing image—and almost completely fictional. Few countries have been less integrated into the global economy.

The country ranks 137 in the world in per-capita income (just behind Tonga and ahead of Kirbati), with a population in the top 20. And while GDP growth for the past few years has been respectable, averaging 4%-5% save for 2009 (when all countries suffered), even that is at best middle of the pack in a period where the more competitive dynamic nations have been surging ahead.

Egypt has long been famous for crony inefficiency. Yet Hosni Mubarak was graced with nearly $2 billion in annual U.S. aid, another $5 billion from dues from the Suez Canal, and $10 billion in tourism, so he could buy off a considerable portion of the 80 million Egyptians.

In modern times, Egypt has been a beacon of hope in the Arab world, with an independence movement led by Gamel Abdel Nasser rising against the remnants of the British empire in 1952. That beacon was kept alive by Nasser's successor Anwar Sadat, who is remembered in the West primarily for his bold overtures to Israel and a peace treaty in 1981 that led to his assassination.

But Sadat's most lasting legacy for Egypt may have been his brief attempt to liberalize the economy (the Infitah) and open the country to the world. While President Mubarak gave lip service to that economic opening, for much of the subsequent three decades Egypt's economy has been locked in a system that stifles economic activity and innovation as surely as it does political expression.

In recent years, Mr. Mubarak seemed to realize that the complete absence of economic reform wasn't tenable. He watched as China surged ahead without loosening the control of the state over political life. He made overtures to regional trade blocs. In fact, a few days before the protests erupted, Mr. Mubarak hosted the second Arab Economic, Development and Social Summit in the resort of Sharm al-Shaikh, calling for more Arab economic integration, regional transportation infrastructure and trade.

But in the past, the changes promised far exceeded the changes effected, and there was little reason to think this time would be different. Mr. Mubarak has resisted calls for political opening with the warning that Muslim fundamentalism would sweep through the land of the Nile.

The world accepted Mr. Mubarak's rationale. Washington focused on the threat of Islamic radicalism and chose to nudge Mr. Mubarak gently rather than risk what he warned would happen if elections were open or expression allowed.

Meanwhile, China ignored the dialectic in the West—which placed political opening at the top of societal imperatives—and plunged into an experiment of hypercharged economic development without political change. Its phenomenal success to date is impossible to refute, just as its future course is impossible to predict.

But Egypt managed to forestall both paths, and its lesson is simple: You can have economic reform, or you can have political reform. You cannot have neither.

What allows China to thrive for now (and Brazil and India and Indonesia, among many others) is that its citizens believe they have some control over their material lives and a chance to turn their dreams and ambitions into reality. They have an outlet for their passions that is not determined for them, and an increasing degree of economic freedom.

The young in Egypt—two-thirds of the population is under the age of 30—believe that they have no future, and in many ways they are correct. Under Mr. Mubarak, their food and housing is subsidized and they are placed in jobs or left in unemployed limbo, not starving but without any hope of anything but years of numbing sameness.

These realities alone don't cause revolution. Many countries are poor and quiet. But Egypt has had all the marks of a tinderbox. The future could bring worse, with radical regimes or chaos. But for millions who have concluded that their dreams for a better life would expire unfulfilled, nothing could be worse than the present.

Mr. Karabell, the president of River Twice Research, is author of "Parting the Desert: The Creation of the Suez Canal (Knopf, 2003), and "Superfusion: How China and America Became One Economy" (Simon & Schuster, 2009).

NY times January 12, 2011

Can Europe Be Saved?

By PAUL KRUGMAN

THERE’S SOMETHING peculiarly apt about the fact that the current European crisis began in Greece. For Europe’s woes have all the aspects of a classical Greek tragedy, in which a man of noble character is undone by the fatal flaw of hubris.

Not long ago Europeans could, with considerable justification, say that the current economic crisis was actually demonstrating the advantages of their economic and social model. Like the United States, Europe suffered a severe slump in the wake of the global financial meltdown; but the human costs of that slump seemed far less in Europe than in America. In much of Europe, rules governing worker firing helped limit job loss, while strong social-welfare programs ensured that even the jobless retained their health care and received a basic income. Europe’s gross domestic product might have fallen as much as ours, but the Europeans weren’t suffering anything like the same amount of misery. And the truth is that they still aren’t.

Yet Europe is in deep crisis — because its proudest achievement, the single currency adopted by most European nations, is now in danger. More than that, it’s looking increasingly like a trap. Ireland, hailed as the Celtic Tiger not so long ago, is now struggling to avoid bankruptcy. Spain, a booming economy until recent years, now has 20 percent unemployment and faces the prospect of years of painful, grinding deflation.

The tragedy of the Euromess is that the creation of the euro was supposed to be the finest moment in a grand and noble undertaking: the generations-long effort to bring peace, democracy and shared prosperity to a once and frequently war-torn continent. But the architects of the euro, caught up in their project’s sweep and romance, chose to ignore the mundane difficulties a shared currency would predictably encounter — to ignore warnings, which were issued right from the beginning, that Europe lacked the institutions needed to make a common currency workable. Instead, they engaged in magical thinking, acting as if the nobility of their mission transcended such concerns.

The result is a tragedy not only for Europe but also for the world, for which Europe is a crucial role model. The Europeans have shown us that peace and unity can be brought to a region with a history of violence, and in the process they have created perhaps the most decent societies in human history, combining democracy and human rights with a level of individual economic security that America comes nowhere close to matching. These achievements are now in the process of being tarnished, as the European dream turns into a nightmare for all too many people. How did that happen?

THE ROAD TO THE EURO
It all began with coal and steel. On May 9, 1950 — a date whose anniversary is now celebrated as Europe Day — Robert Schuman, the French foreign minister, proposed that his nation and West Germany pool their coal and steel production. That may sound prosaic, but Schuman declared that it was much more than just a business deal.

For one thing, the new Coal and Steel Community would make any future war between Germany and France “not merely unthinkable, but materially impossible.” And it would be a first step on the road to a “federation of Europe,” to be achieved step by step via “concrete achievements which first create a de facto solidarity.” That is, economic measures would both serve mundane ends and promote political unity.

The Coal and Steel Community eventually evolved into a customs union within which all goods were freely traded. Then, as democracy spread within Europe, so did Europe’s unifying economic institutions. Greece, Spain and Portugal were brought in after the fall of their dictatorships; Eastern Europe after the fall of Communism.

In the 1980s and ’90s this “widening” was accompanied by “deepening,” as Europe set about removing many of the remaining obstacles to full economic integration. (Eurospeak is a distinctive dialect, sometimes hard to understand without subtitles.) Borders were opened; freedom of personal movement was guaranteed; and product, safety and food regulations were harmonized, a process immortalized by the Eurosausage episode of the TV show “Yes Minister,” in which the minister in question is told that under new European rules, the traditional British sausage no longer qualifies as a sausage and must be renamed the Emulsified High-Fat Offal Tube. (Just to be clear, this happened only on TV.)

The creation of the euro was proclaimed the logical next step in this process. Once again, economic growth would be fostered with actions that also reinforced European unity.

The advantages of a single European currency were obvious. No more need to change money when you arrived in another country; no more uncertainty on the part of importers about what a contract would actually end up costing or on the part of exporters about what promised payment would actually be worth. Meanwhile, the shared currency would strengthen the sense of European unity. What could go wrong?

The answer, unfortunately, was that currency unions have costs as well as benefits. And the case for a single European currency was much weaker than the case for a single European market — a fact that European leaders chose to ignore.

THE (UNEASY) CASE FOR MONETARY UNION
International monetary economics is, not surprisingly, an area of frequent disputes. As it happens, however, these disputes don’t line up across the usual ideological divide. The hard right often favors hard money — preferably a gold standard — but left-leaning European politicians have been enthusiastic proponents of the euro. Liberal American economists, myself included, tend to favor freely floating national currencies that leave more scope for activist economic policies — in particular, cutting interest rates and increasing the money supply to fight recessions. Yet the classic argument for flexible exchange rates was made by none other than Milton Friedman.

The case for a transnational currency is, as we’ve already seen, obvious: it makes doing business easier. Before the euro was introduced, it was really anybody’s guess how much this ultimately mattered: there were relatively few examples of countries using other nations’ currencies. For what it was worth, statistical analysis suggested that adopting a common currency had big effects on trade, which suggested in turn large economic gains. Unfortunately, this optimistic assessment hasn’t held up very well since the euro was created: the best estimates now indicate that trade among euro nations is only 10 or 15 percent larger than it would have been otherwise. That’s not a trivial number, but neither is it transformative.

Still, there are obviously benefits from a currency union. It’s just that there’s a downside, too: by giving up its own currency, a country also gives up economic flexibility.

Imagine that you’re a country that, like Spain today, recently saw wages and prices driven up by a housing boom, which then went bust. Now you need to get those costs back down. But getting wages and prices to fall is tough: nobody wants to be the first to take a pay cut, especially without some assurance that prices will come down, too. Two years of intense suffering have brought Irish wages down to some extent, although Spain and Greece have barely begun the process. It’s a nasty affair, and as we’ll see later, cutting wages when you’re awash in debt creates new problems.

If you still have your own currency, however, you wouldn’t have to go through the protracted pain of cutting wages: you could just devalue your currency — reduce its value in terms of other currencies — and you would effect a de facto wage cut.

Won’t workers reject de facto wage cuts via devaluation just as much as explicit cuts in their paychecks? Historical experience says no. In the current crisis, it took Ireland two years of severe unemployment to achieve about a 5 percent reduction in average wages. But in 1993 a devaluation of the Irish punt brought an instant 10 percent reduction in Irish wages measured in German currency.

Why the difference? Back in 1953, Milton Friedman offered an analogy: daylight saving time. It makes a lot of sense for businesses to open later during the winter months, yet it’s hard for any individual business to change its hours: if you operate from 10 to 6 when everyone else is operating 9 to 5, you’ll be out of sync. By requiring that everyone shift clocks back in the fall and forward in the spring, daylight saving time obviates this coordination problem. Similarly, Friedman argued, adjusting your currency’s value solves the coordination problem when wages and prices are out of line, sidestepping the unwillingness of workers to be the first to take pay cuts.

So while there are benefits of a common currency, there are also important potential advantages to keeping your own currency. And the terms of this trade-off depend on underlying conditions.

On one side, the benefits of a shared currency depend on how much business would be affected.

I think of this as the Iceland-Brooklyn issue. Iceland, with only 320,000 people, has its own currency — and that fact has given it valuable room for maneuver. So why isn’t Brooklyn, with roughly eight times Iceland’s population, an even better candidate for an independent currency? The answer is that Brooklyn, located as it is in the middle of metro New York rather than in the middle of the Atlantic, has an economy deeply enmeshed with those of neighboring boroughs. And Brooklyn residents would pay a large price if they had to change currencies every time they did business in Manhattan or Queens.

So countries that do a lot of business with one another may have a lot to gain from a currency union.

On the other hand, as Friedman pointed out, forming a currency union means sacrificing flexibility. How serious is this loss? That depends. Let’s consider what may at first seem like an odd comparison between two small, troubled economies.

Climate, scenery and history aside, the nation of Ireland and the state of Nevada have much in common. Both are small economies of a few million people highly dependent on selling goods and services to their neighbors. (Nevada’s neighbors are other U.S. states, Ireland’s other European nations, but the economic implications are much the same.) Both were boom economies for most of the past decade. Both had huge housing bubbles, which burst painfully. Both are now suffering roughly 14 percent unemployment. And both are members of larger currency unions: Ireland is part of the euro zone, Nevada part of the dollar zone, otherwise known as the United States of America.

But Nevada’s situation is much less desperate than Ireland’s.

First of all, the fiscal side of the crisis is less serious in Nevada. It’s true that budgets in both Ireland and Nevada have been hit extremely hard by the slump. But much of the spending Nevada residents depend on comes from federal, not state, programs. In particular, retirees who moved to Nevada for the sunshine don’t have to worry that the state’s reduced tax take will endanger their Social Security checks or their Medicare coverage. In Ireland, by contrast, both pensions and health spending are on the cutting block.

Also, Nevada, unlike Ireland, doesn’t have to worry about the cost of bank bailouts, not because the state has avoided large loan losses but because those losses, for the most part, aren’t Nevada’s problem. Thus Nevada accounts for a disproportionate share of the losses incurred by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the government-sponsored mortgage companies — losses that, like Social Security and Medicare payments, will be covered by Washington, not Carson City.

And there’s one more advantage to being a U.S. state: it’s likely that Nevada’s unemployment problem will be greatly alleviated over the next few years by out-migration, so that even if the lost jobs don’t come back, there will be fewer workers chasing the jobs that remain. Ireland will, to some extent, avail itself of the same safety valve, as Irish citizens leave in search of work elsewhere and workers who came to Ireland during the boom years depart. But Americans are extremely mobile; if historical patterns are any guide, emigration will bring Nevada’s unemployment rate back in line with the U.S. average within a few years, even if job growth in Nevada continues to lag behind growth in the nation as a whole.

Over all, then, even as both Ireland and Nevada have been especially hard-luck cases within their respective currency zones, Nevada’s medium-term prospects look much better.

What does this have to do with the case for or against the euro? Well, when the single European currency was first proposed, an obvious question was whether it would work as well as the dollar does here in America. And the answer, clearly, was no — for exactly the reasons the Ireland-Nevada comparison illustrates. Europe isn’t fiscally integrated: German taxpayers don’t automatically pick up part of the tab for Greek pensions or Irish bank bailouts. And while Europeans have the legal right to move freely in search of jobs, in practice imperfect cultural integration — above all, the lack of a common language — makes workers less geographically mobile than their American counterparts.

And now you see why many American (and some British) economists have always been skeptical about the euro project. U.S.-based economists had long emphasized the importance of certain preconditions for currency union — most famously, Robert Mundell of Columbia stressed the importance of labor mobility, while Peter Kenen, my colleague at Princeton, emphasized the importance of fiscal integration. America, we know, has a currency union that works, and we know why it works: because it coincides with a nation — a nation with a big central government, a common language and a shared culture. Europe has none of these things, which from the beginning made the prospects of a single currency dubious.

These observations aren’t new: everything I’ve just said was well known by 1992, when the Maastricht Treaty set the euro project in motion. So why did the project proceed? Because the idea of the euro had gripped the imagination of European elites. Except in Britain, where Gordon Brown persuaded Tony Blair not to join, political leaders throughout Europe were caught up in the romance of the project, to such an extent that anyone who expressed skepticism was considered outside the mainstream.

Back in the ’90s, people who were present told me that staff members at the European Commission were initially instructed to prepare reports on the costs and benefits of a single currency — but that after their superiors got a look at some preliminary work, those instructions were altered: they were told to prepare reports just on the benefits. To be fair, when I’ve told that story to others who were senior officials at the time, they’ve disputed that — but whoever’s version is right, the fact that some people were making such a claim captures the spirit of the time.

The euro, then, would proceed. And for a while, everything seemed to go well.

EUROPHORIA, EUROCRISIS
The euro officially came into existence on Jan. 1, 1999. At first it was a virtual currency: bank accounts and electronic transfers were denominated in euros, but people still had francs, marks and lira (now considered denominations of the euro) in their wallets. Three years later, the final transition was made, and the euro became Europe’s money.

The transition was smooth: A.T.M.’s and cash registers were converted swiftly and with few glitches. The euro quickly became a major international currency: the euro bond market soon came to rival the dollar bond market; euro bank notes began circulating around the world. And the creation of the euro instilled a new sense of confidence, especially in those European countries that had historically been considered investment risks. Only later did it become apparent that this surge of confidence was bait for a dangerous trap.

Greece, with its long history of debt defaults and bouts of high inflation, was the most striking example. Until the late 1990s, Greece’s fiscal history was reflected in its bond yields: investors would buy bonds issued by the Greek government only if they paid much higher interest than bonds issued by governments perceived as safe bets, like those by Germany. As the euro’s debut approached, however, the risk premium on Greek bonds melted away. After all, the thinking went, Greek debt would soon be immune from the dangers of inflation: the European Central Bank would see to that. And it wasn’t possible to imagine any member of the newly minted monetary union going bankrupt, was it?

Indeed, by the middle of the 2000s just about all fear of country-specific fiscal woes had vanished from the European scene. Greek bonds, Irish bonds, Spanish bonds, Portuguese bonds — they all traded as if they were as safe as German bonds. The aura of confidence extended even to countries that weren’t on the euro yet but were expected to join in the near future: by 2005, Latvia, which at that point hoped to adopt the euro by 2008, was able to borrow almost as cheaply as Ireland. (Latvia’s switch to the euro has been put off for now, although neighboring Estonia joined on Jan. 1.)

As interest rates converged across Europe, the formerly high-interest-rate countries went, predictably, on a borrowing spree. (This borrowing spree was, it’s worth noting, largely financed by banks in Germany and other traditionally low-interest-rate countries; that’s why the current debt problems of the European periphery are also a big problem for the European banking system as a whole.) In Greece it was largely the government that ran up big debts. But elsewhere, private players were the big borrowers. Ireland, as I’ve already noted, had a huge real estate boom: home prices rose 180 percent from 1998, just before the euro was introduced, to 2007. Prices in Spain rose almost as much. There were booms in those not-yet-euro nations, too: money flooded into Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Bulgaria and Romania.

It was a heady time, and not only for the borrowers. In the late 1990s, Germany’s economy was depressed as a result of low demand from domestic consumers. But it recovered in the decade that followed, thanks to an export boom driven by its European neighbors’ spending sprees.

Everything, in short, seemed to be going swimmingly: the euro was pronounced a great success.

Then the bubble burst.

You still hear people talking about the global economic crisis of 2008 as if it were something made in America. But Europe deserves equal billing. This was, if you like, a North Atlantic crisis, with not much to choose between the messes of the Old World and the New. We had our subprime borrowers, who either chose to take on or were misled into taking on mortgages too big for their incomes; they had their peripheral economies, which similarly borrowed much more than they could really afford to pay back. In both cases, real estate bubbles temporarily masked the underlying unsustainability of the borrowing: as long as housing prices kept rising, borrowers could always pay back previous loans with more money borrowed against their properties. Sooner or later, however, the music would stop. Both sides of the Atlantic were accidents waiting to happen.

In Europe, the first round of damage came from the collapse of those real estate bubbles, which devastated employment in the peripheral economies. In 2007, construction accounted for 13 percent of total employment in both Spain and Ireland, more than twice as much as in the United States. So when the building booms came to a screeching halt, employment crashed. Overall employment fell 10 percent in Spain and 14 percent in Ireland; the Irish situation would be the equivalent of losing almost 20 million jobs here.

But that was only the beginning. In late 2009, as much of the world was emerging from financial crisis, the European crisis entered a new phase. First Greece, then Ireland, then Spain and Portugal suffered drastic losses in investor confidence and hence a significant rise in borrowing costs. Why?

In Greece the story is straightforward: the government behaved irresponsibly, lied about it and got caught. During the years of easy borrowing, Greece’s conservative government ran up a lot of debt — more than it admitted. When the government changed hands in 2009, the accounting fictions came to light; suddenly it was revealed that Greece had both a much bigger deficit and substantially more debt than anyone had realized. Investors, understandably, took flight.

But Greece is actually an unrepresentative case. Just a few years ago Spain, by far the largest of the crisis economies, was a model European citizen, with a balanced budget and public debt only about half as large, as a percentage of G.D.P., as that of Germany. The same was true for Ireland. So what went wrong?

First, there was a large direct fiscal hit from the slump. Revenue plunged in both Spain and Ireland, in part because tax receipts depended heavily on real estate transactions. Meanwhile, as unemployment soared, so did the cost of unemployment benefits — remember, these are European welfare states, which have much more extensive programs to shield their citizens from misfortune than we do. As a result, both Spain and Ireland went from budget surpluses on the eve of the crisis to huge budget deficits by 2009.

Then there were the costs of financial clean-up. These have been especially crippling in Ireland, where banks ran wild in the boom years (and were allowed to do so thanks to close personal and financial ties with government officials). When the bubble burst, the solvency of Irish banks was immediately suspect. In an attempt to avert a massive run on the financial system, Ireland’s government guaranteed all bank debts — saddling the government itself with those debts, bringing its own solvency into question. Big Spanish banks were well regulated by comparison, but there was and is a great deal of nervousness about the status of smaller savings banks and concern about how much the Spanish government will have to spend to keep these banks from collapsing.

All of this helps explain why lenders have lost faith in peripheral European economies. Still, there are other nations — in particular, both the United States and Britain — that have been running deficits that, as a percentage of G.D.P., are comparable to the deficits in Spain and Ireland. Yet they haven’t suffered a comparable loss of lender confidence. What is different about the euro countries?

One possible answer is “nothing”: maybe one of these days we’ll wake up and find that the markets are shunning America, just as they’re shunning Greece. But the real answer is probably more systemic: it’s the euro itself that makes Spain and Ireland so vulnerable. For membership in the euro means that these countries have to deflate their way back to competitiveness, with all the pain that implies.

The trouble with deflation isn’t just the coordination problem Milton Friedman highlighted, in which it’s hard to get wages and prices down when everyone wants someone else to move first. Even when countries successfully drive down wages, which is now happening in all the euro-crisis countries, they run into another problem: incomes are falling, but debt is not.

As the American economist Irving Fisher pointed out almost 80 years ago, the collision between deflating incomes and unchanged debt can greatly worsen economic downturns. Suppose the economy slumps, for whatever reason: spending falls and so do prices and wages. But debts do not, so debtors have to meet the same obligations with a smaller income; to do this, they have to cut spending even more, further depressing the economy. The way to avoid this vicious circle, Fisher said, was monetary expansion that heads off deflation. And in America and Britain, the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England, respectively, are trying to do just that. But Greece, Spain and Ireland don’t have that option — they don’t even have their own monies, and in any case they need deflation to get their costs in line.

And so there’s a crisis. Over the course of the past year or so, first Greece, then Ireland, became caught up in a vicious financial circle: as potential lenders lost confidence, the interest rates that they had to pay on the debt rose, undermining future prospects, leading to a further loss of confidence and even higher interest rates. Stronger European nations averted an immediate implosion only by providing Greece and Ireland with emergency credit lines, letting them bypass private markets for the time being. But how is this all going to work out?

FOUR EUROPEAN PLOTLINES
Some economists, myself included, look at Europe’s woes and have the feeling that we’ve seen this movie before, a decade ago on another continent — specifically, in Argentina.

Unlike Spain or Greece, Argentina never gave up its own currency, but in 1991 it did the next best thing: it rigidly pegged its currency to the U.S. dollar, establishing a “currency board” in which each peso in circulation was backed by a dollar in reserves. This was supposed to prevent any return to Argentina’s old habit of covering its deficits by printing money. And for much of the 1990s, Argentina was rewarded with much lower interest rates and large inflows of foreign capital.

Eventually, however, Argentina slid into a persistent recession and lost investor confidence. Argentina’s government tried to restore that confidence through rigorous fiscal orthodoxy, slashing spending and raising taxes. To buy time for austerity to have a positive effect, Argentina sought and received large loans from the International Monetary Fund — in much the same way that Greece and Ireland have sought emergency loans from their neighbors. But the persistent decline of the Argentine economy, combined with deflation, frustrated the government’s efforts, even as high unemployment led to growing unrest.

By early 2002, after angry demonstrations and a run on the banks, it had all fallen apart. The link between the peso and the dollar collapsed, with the peso plunging; meanwhile, Argentina defaulted on its debts, eventually paying only about 35 cents on the dollar.

It’s hard to avoid the suspicion that something similar may be in the cards for one or more of Europe’s problem economies. After all, the policies now being undertaken by the crisis countries are, qualitatively at least, very similar to those Argentina tried in its desperate effort to save the peso-dollar link: harsh fiscal austerity in an effort to regain the market’s confidence, backed in Greece and Ireland by official loans intended to buy time until private lenders regain confidence. And if an Argentine-style outcome is the end of the line, it will be a terrible blow to the euro project. Is that what’s going to happen?

Not necessarily. As I see it, there are four ways the European crisis could play out (and it may play out differently in different countries). Call them toughing it out; debt restructuring; full Argentina; and revived Europeanism.

Toughing it out: Troubled European economies could, conceivably, reassure creditors by showing sufficient willingness to endure pain and thereby avoid either default or devaluation. The role models here are the Baltic nations: Estonia, Lithuania and Latvia. These countries are small and poor by European standards; they want very badly to gain the long-term advantages they believe will accrue from joining the euro and becoming part of a greater Europe. And so they have been willing to endure very harsh fiscal austerity while wages gradually come down in the hope of restoring competitiveness — a process known in Eurospeak as “internal devaluation.”

Have these policies been successful? It depends on how you define “success.” The Baltic nations have, to some extent, succeeded in reassuring markets, which now consider them less risky than Ireland, let alone Greece. Meanwhile, wages have come down, declining 15 percent in Latvia and more than 10 percent in Lithuania and Estonia. All of this has, however, come at immense cost: the Baltics have experienced Depression-level declines in output and employment. It’s true that they’re now growing again, but all indications are that it will be many years before they make up the lost ground.

It says something about the current state of Europe that many officials regard the Baltics as a success story. I find myself quoting Tacitus: “They make a desert and call it peace” — or, in this case, adjustment. Still, this is one way the euro zone could survive intact.

Debt restructuring: At the time of writing, Irish 10-year bonds were yielding about 9 percent, while Greek 10-years were yielding 12½ percent. At the same time, German 10-years — which, like Irish and Greek bonds, are denominated in euros — were yielding less than 3 percent. The message from the markets was clear: investors don’t expect Greece and Ireland to pay their debts in full. They are, in other words, expecting some kind of debt restructuring, like the restructuring that reduced Argentina’s debt by two-thirds.

 

 

Such a debt restructuring would by no means end a troubled economy’s pain. Take Greece: even if the government were to repudiate all its debt, it would still have to slash spending and raise taxes to balance its budget, and it would still have to suffer the pain of deflation. But a debt restructuring could bring the vicious circle of falling confidence and rising interest costs to an end, potentially making internal devaluation a workable if brutal strategy.

Frankly, I find it hard to see how Greece can avoid a debt restructuring, and Ireland isn’t much better. The real question is whether such restructurings will spread to Spain and — the truly frightening prospect — to Belgium and Italy, which are heavily indebted but have so far managed to avoid a serious crisis of confidence.

Full Argentina: Argentina didn’t simply default on its foreign debt; it also abandoned its link to the dollar, allowing the peso’s value to fall by more than two-thirds. And this devaluation worked: from 2003 onward, Argentina experienced a rapid export-led economic rebound.

The European country that has come closest to doing an Argentina is Iceland, whose bankers had run up foreign debts that were many times its national income. Unlike Ireland, which tried to salvage its banks by guaranteeing their debts, the Icelandic government forced its banks’ foreign creditors to take losses, thereby limiting its debt burden. And by letting its banks default, the country took a lot of foreign debt off its national books.

At the same time, Iceland took advantage of the fact that it had not joined the euro and still had its own currency. It soon became more competitive by letting its currency drop sharply against other currencies, including the euro. Iceland’s wages and prices quickly fell about 40 percent relative to those of its trading partners, sparking a rise in exports and fall in imports that helped offset the blow from the banking collapse.

The combination of default and devaluation has helped Iceland limit the damage from its banking disaster. In fact, in terms of employment and output, Iceland has done somewhat better than Ireland and much better than the Baltic nations.

So will one or more troubled European nations go down the same path? To do so, they would have to overcome a big obstacle: the fact that, unlike Iceland, they no longer have their own currencies. As Barry Eichengreen of Berkeley pointed out in an influential 2007 analysis, any euro-zone country that even hinted at leaving the currency would trigger a devastating run on its banks, as depositors rushed to move their funds to safer locales. And Eichengreen concluded that this “procedural” obstacle to exit made the euro irreversible.

But Argentina’s peg to the dollar was also supposed to be irreversible, and for much the same reason. What made devaluation possible, in the end, was the fact that there was a run on the banks despite the government’s insistence that one peso would always be worth one dollar. This run forced the Argentine government to limit withdrawals, and once these limits were in place, it was possible to change the peso’s value without setting off a second run. Nothing like that has happened in Europe — yet. But it’s certainly within the realm of possibility, especially as the pain of austerity and internal devaluation drags on.

Revived Europeanism: The preceding three scenarios were grim. Is there any hope of an outcome less grim? To the extent that there is, it would have to involve taking further major steps toward that “European federation” Robert Schuman wanted 60 years ago.

In early December, Jean-Claude Juncker, the prime minister of Luxembourg, and Giulio Tremonti, Italy’s finance minister, created a storm with a proposal to create “E-bonds,” which would be issued by a European debt agency at the behest of individual European countries. Since these bonds would be guaranteed by the European Union as a whole, they would offer a way for troubled economies to avoid vicious circles of falling confidence and rising borrowing costs. On the other hand, they would potentially put governments on the hook for one another’s debts — a point that furious German officials were quick to make. The Germans are adamant that Europe must not become a “transfer union,” in which stronger governments and nations routinely provide aid to weaker.

Yet as the earlier Ireland-Nevada comparison shows, the United States works as a currency union in large part precisely because it is also a transfer union, in which states that haven’t gone bust support those that have. And it’s hard to see how the euro can work unless Europe finds a way to accomplish something similar.

Nobody is yet proposing that Europe move to anything resembling U.S. fiscal integration; the Juncker-Tremonti plan would be at best a small step in that direction. But Europe doesn’t seem ready to take even that modest step.

OUT OF MANY, ONE?
For now, the plan in Europe is to have everyone tough it out — in effect, for Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain to emulate Latvia and Estonia. That was the clear verdict of the most recent meeting of the European Council, at which Angela Merkel, the German chancellor, essentially got everything she wanted. Governments that can’t borrow on the private market will receive loans from the rest of Europe — but only on stiff terms: people talk about Ireland getting a “bailout,” but it has to pay almost 6 percent interest on that emergency loan. There will be no E-bonds; there will be no transfer union.

Even if this eventually works in the sense that internal devaluation has worked in the Baltics — that is, in the narrow sense that Europe’s troubled economies avoid default and devaluation — it will be an ugly process, leaving much of Europe deeply depressed for years to come. There will be political repercussions too, as the European public sees the continent’s institutions as being — depending on where they sit — either in the business of bailing out deadbeats or acting as agents of heartless bill collectors.

Nor can the rest of the world look on smugly at Europe’s woes. Taken as a whole, the European Union, not the United States, is the world’s largest economy; the European Union is fully coequal with America in the running of the global trading system; Europe is the world’s most important source of foreign aid; and Europe is, whatever some Americans may think, a crucial partner in the fight against terrorism. A troubled Europe is bad for everyone else.

In any case, the odds are that the current tough-it-out strategy won’t work even in the narrow sense of avoiding default and devaluation — and the fact that it won’t work will become obvious sooner rather than later. At that point, Europe’s stronger nations will have to make a choice.

It has been 60 years since the Schuman declaration started Europe on the road to greater unity. Until now the journey along that road, however slow, has always been in the right direction. But that will no longer be true if the euro project fails. A failed euro wouldn’t send Europe back to the days of minefields and barbed wire — but it would represent a possibly irreversible blow to hopes of true European federation.

So will Europe’s strong nations let that happen? Or will they accept the responsibility, and possibly the cost, of being their neighbors’ keepers? The whole world is waiting for the answer.

Paul Krugman is a Times columnist and winner of the 2008 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. His latest book is “The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008.”

January 31, 2011

DDT Still Critical in Fight against Insect-Borne Diseases

Through a mix of environmental fervor, self-interest and disregard for evidence-based policy, United Nations (UN) agencies are misleading the public about the insecticide DDT -- mistakenly claiming it is not needed and can be eliminated globally by 2020, says Donald Roberts, emeritus professor of tropical medicine at Uniformed Services University of the Health Sciences, Roger Bate, the Legatum Fellow in Global Prosperity at the American Enterprise Institute, and Richard Tren, the executive director of Africa Fighting Malaria.

  • UN agencies are misleading the public by claiming that malaria can be controlled without insecticides, notably DDT; the stated aim is to stop DDT use globally by 2020.
  • UN agencies are committing scientific fraud by deliberately and incorrectly interpreting data on malaria control using noninsecticide methods.

While DDT is no panacea, it is still a critical weapon in the battle against malaria and other insect-borne diseases, say Roberts, Bate and Tren.

Source: Roger Bate, Donald Roberts and Richard Tren, "The United Nations' Scientific Fraud against DDT," American Enterprise Institute, January 21, 2011.

For text:

http://www.aei.org/outlook/101019  

 

 

World Income Inequality

Alex Tabarrok

Here, courtesy of Catherine Rampell of Economix, is a remarkable chart from Branko Milanovic's book The Haves and Have Nots. Along the horizontal axis are within-country income percentiles running from the bottom 5% (1st ventile) to the top 5% (20th ventile). Along the vertical axis are world income percentiles.

Economix-28milanovic-custom1
The graph shows that the bottom 5% of Brazilians are among the poorest people in the world but the top 5% are among the richest. Thus the vertical range of the curve tells us about within-country inequality.

Comparing between countries we see that the poorest 5% of Americans are among the richest people in the world (richer than nearly 70% of other people in the world). The poorest 5% of Americans, for example, are richer than the richest 5% of Indians.

January 31, 2011 at 12:21 PM in Data Source, Economics | Permalink | Comments (58)

 

 

 

N Y Times January 28, 2011, 7:46 pm

The Wal-Mart Decade

I’ve been putting some material together for textbook revision, and found myself looking at European versus US productivity performance over the past couple of decades. I sort of knew the facts here, but this recent paper by Bart van Ark (pdf) seemed to me to make the points especially clearly, and I found myself rolling my own versions of some of his numbers.

To get some sense of productivity trends, van Ark uses a fairly fancy statistical technique (Hodrick-Prescott filter). But a simple 5-year moving average, to smooth out the business cycle, does about the same thing. Here’s productivity growth in the US and in “Europe” defined as the average of the 4 big economies since 1970:

Total Economy Database

European productivity grew faster than the US until the 1990s, mainly reflecting catchup; but America moved ahead in the late 1990s; the data suggest that the differential has leveled out since, so this may have been a one-time bulge.

And what was it about? Van Ark’s data point to a huge surge between 1995 and 2004 in US productivity, not so much in producing goods as in distributing them. And we know what that’s about: Wal-Mart and other big box stores.

I’m not denigrating these productivity gains. What’s interesting, though, is that if you’re looking for a story about the relative American revival from 1995 until recently, it’s not so much a broad, generic economy thing as it is a story of one particular innovation that for whatever reason — land use regulations? — Europe was slow to imitate.

 

Marginal Revolution  2-1-11

Five-year average productivity

Tyler Cowen

 
That is from Paul Krugman.  And from Krugman's source, Bart van Ark:

To conclude, there is good reason to adjust the long-term US productivity growth rate downwards.

January 29, 2011 at 07:07 AM in Economics | Permalink | Comments (23

 

 

Innovation Is Doing Little for Incomes

By TYLER COWEN
Published: January 29, 2011 N Y Times

 

MY grandmother, who was born in 1905, spoke often about the immense changes she had seen, including the widespread adoption of electricity, the automobile, flush toilets, antibiotics and convenient household appliances. Since my birth in 1962, it seems to me, there have not been comparable improvements.

David G. Klein

Of course, the personal computer and its cousin, the smartphone, have brought about some big changes. And many goods and services are now more plentiful and of better quality. But compared with what my grandmother witnessed, the basic accouterments of life have remained broadly the same.

The income numbers for Americans reflect this slowdown in growth. From 1947 to 1973 — a period of just 26 years — inflation-adjusted median income in the United States more than doubled. But in the 31 years from 1973 to 2004, it rose only 22 percent. And, over the last decade, it actually declined.

Most well-off countries have experienced income growth slowdowns since the early 1970s, so it would seem that a single cause is transcending national borders: the reaching of a technological plateau. The numbers suggest that for almost 40 years, we’ve had near-universal dissemination of the major innovations stemming from the Industrial Revolution, many of which combined efficient machines with potent fossil fuels. Today, no huge improvement for the automobile or airplane is in sight, and the major struggle is to limit their pollution, not to vastly improve their capabilities.

Although America produces plenty of innovations, most are not geared toward significantly raising the average standard of living. It seems that we are coming up with ideas that benefit relatively small numbers of people, compared with the broad-based advances of earlier decades, when the modern world was put into place. If pre-1973 growth rates had continued, for example, median family income in the United States would now be more than $90,000, as opposed to its current range of around $50,000.

Will the Internet usher in a new economic growth explosion? Quite possibly, but it hasn’t delivered very good macroeconomic performance over the last decade. Many of the Internet’s gains are fun — games, chat rooms, Twitter streams — rather than vast sources of revenue, and when there have been measurable monetary gains, they often have been concentrated among a small number of company founders, as with, say, Facebook. As for users, the Internet has benefited the well-educated and the curious to a disproportionate degree, but apparently not enough to bolster median income.

Beyond the income slowdown, there is a further worry: an increasing share of the economy consists of education and health care. That trend is not necessarily bad, but in these two areas, results are often hard to measure. If health care costs rise 6 percent in a year, for example, that counts as higher G.D.P., but how much is our health actually improving? It’s an open question. America spends more on health care than other countries, but those expenditures don’t seem to produce uniformly superior results. And while there have certainly been gains in medical treatment, we may be overvaluing them. In education, we are spending more each year, but test scores have stagnated for decades, graduation rates are down and America’s worst schools are disasters.

There is an even broader problem. When it comes to measuring national income, we’re generally valuing expenditures at cost, rather than tracking productivity in terms of results. In other words, our statistics may be deceiving us — by accepting, say, our health care and educational expenditures at face value. This theme has been emphasized by the PayPal co-founder Peter Thiel in his public talks and by the economist Michael Mandel in his writings. And I’ve stressed it in a recent e-book, “The Great Stagnation.”

Sooner or later, new technological revolutions will occur, perhaps in the biosciences, through genome sequencing, or in energy production, through viable solar power, for example. But these transformations won’t come overnight, and we’ll have to make do in the meantime. Instead of facing up to this scarcity, politicians promote tax cuts and income redistribution policies to benefit favored constituencies. Yet these are one-off adjustments and, over time, they cannot undo the slower rate of growth in average living standards.

It’s unclear whether Americans have the temperament to make a smooth transition to a more stagnant economy. After all, we’ve long thought of our country as the land of unlimited opportunity. In practice, this optimism has meant that we continue to increase government spending, whether or not we can afford it.

In the narrow sense, the solution to the stagnation of median income will not be a political one. And one of the hardest points to grasp about this quandary is that no one in particular is to blame. Scientific progress has never proceeded on an even, predictable basis, even though for part of the 20th century it seemed that it might.

Science should be encouraged with subsidies for basic research, as well as private charity, educational reform, a business culture geared toward commercializing inventions, and greater public appreciation for the scientific endeavor. A lighter legal and regulatory hand could ease the path of future innovations.

NONETHELESS, advancing discovery is not a goal to be reached by the mere application of will. Precisely because there is no obvious villain and no simple fix, and many complex factors behind success, science as a general topic doesn’t play a big role in American political discourse. When it comes to understanding our macroeconomic predicament, we often seem to be missing the point.

Until science has a greater impact again on average daily living standards, the political problem will be in learning to live within our means. Because neither major party seems to support a plausible path to fiscal balance, or to acknowledge how little control politicians actually have over future income growth, we unscientifically keep living in an age of denial.

Tyler Cowen is a professor of economics at George Mason University.

A version of this article appeared in print on January 30, 2011, on page BU4 of the New York edition.

 

MR  Feb 1 2011

Median-itis and The Great Stagnation

Tyler Cowen

Here is my NYT column from today, on themes relevant to The Great Stagnation.  I won't rehash this entire discussion, but I would like to focus on this one column excerpt:

From 1947 to 1973 — a period of just 26 years — inflation-adjusted median income in the United States more than doubled. But in the 31 years from 1973 to 2004, it rose only 22 percent. And, over the last decade, it actually declined.

I am noticing that some reviews or commentaries (and here) are citing per capita income growth as a response to my argument.  It is true that per capita income grows at a slower rate post-1973, but my argument is about the slowing down of median income growth and that is a much stronger shift.  The productivity data also tell a glum story.   

CPI bias can change those numbers in absolute terms (see comments from Russ Roberts), but it also changes the pre-1973 median income growth numbers and arguably more soThe gap remains and TGS refers to the living standard for the average person or household in the United States, not the total amount of innovation, which remains quite high.  They're just not innovations with the same trickle-down or broad-based effects as in an earlier era.

Kindle eBooks are themselves a good example.  It's a real improvement for a lot of us -- especially travelers -- but even the median reader, much less the median American, doesn't have a Kindle or buy eBooks.  As I argued in The Age of the Infovore, the big gains of late have gone to the extreme information-processors.  

I've seen in the MR comments (and elsewhere) a lot of anecdotal comparison of recent gains vs. earlier gains in technology.  Don't we now have this, don't we now have that, and so on.  Of course.  Median incomes have risen somewhat.  But, when it comes to the average household, the published numbers for median income are adding up and trying to measure those gains and it turns out their recent rate of growth really has declined.  Most serious researchers who work in this area use and accept these numbers as the best available (though they do not in general advocate my causal interpretation; see for instance Mark Thoma or Jacob Hacker).  

If the numbers for median income growth are low we ought to take that seriously, as does Scott Sumner.  We are not cheerleaders per se (BC: "I'm baffled why Tyler would focus on slight declines in American growth when the world just had the best decade ever."  Is it then wrong to focus on any other problems at all?  I also was one of the first people to make the "best decade ever" argument, which I still accept.)  Medians also matter for the political climate, even though the median earner is not exactly the median voter.  Adam Smith's welfare economics was basically that of the median, a point which David Levy has made repeatedly.

I'm also being called a "pessimist" a lot.  Yet in my view our current technological plateau won't last forever.  That's probably more optimistic than the Hacker-Pierson approach, which requires a Progressive revolution in economic policy (unlikely), although it is not more optimistic than denying the relevance of the numbers.

I'll soon blog some remarks on changing household size as another attempt to avoid confronting the facts about slow median income growth.

January 30, 2011 at 07:53 AM in Books, Data Source, Economics | Permalink | Comments (62)

 

The Kitchen Test

Tyler Cowen

Here is Paul Krugman, noting that innovations for the kitchen have slowed down.  He cites this earlier, mid-90s piece of his on kitchens, which I would have cited had I known about it.  His conclusion:

By any reasonable standard, the change in how America lived between 1918 and 1957 was immensely greater than the change between 1957 and the present.

As Krugman did in the mid-1990s, I now cook in a 1950s kitchen and it suits me fine.  I use the microwave reluctantly and when I first met Natasha, eight years ago, she and Yana thought it noteworthy that I did not know how to use the device at all.  I do not see that my cooking stands at a disadvantage.

Alexander J. Field has a long and very good piece on the evolution of kitchen technology.  He concludes:

Aside from the automatic dishwasher in the 1930s (which achieved significant penetration only beginning in the 1960s), the garbage disposer (introduced in the 1950s, but low penetration until the late 1960s) and the microwave oven in the 1970s, there have been no truly revolutionary kitchen appliances in the last eight decades.

Field makes good fun of the electric can opener and the electric carving knife.

Here is a related Krugman post on the 19th century.

N Y Times  January 31, 2011, 9:35 am

The Haves and the Have-Nots

By CATHERINE RAMPELL

12:51 p.m. | Updated Updated with additional explanation of how the chart controls for different costs of living around the world.

I had a review this weekend about “ The Haves and the Have-Nots,” a new book by the World Bank economist  Branko Milanovic about inequality around the world. My favorite part of the book was this graph, next to which I actually wrote “awesome chart” in the margin:

Branko Milanovic, “The Haves and the Have-Nots,” p. 116.

The graph shows inequality within a country, in the context of inequality around the world. It can take a few minutes to get your bearings with this chart, but trust me, it’s worth it.

Here the population of each country is divided into 20 equally-sized income groups, ranked by their household per-capita income. These are called “ventiles,” as you can see on the horizontal axis, and each “ventile” translates to a cluster of five percentiles.

The household income numbers are all converted into  international dollars adjusted for equal purchasing power, since the cost of goods varies from country to country. In other words, the chart adjusts for the cost of living in different countries, so we are looking at consistent living standards worldwide.

Now on the vertical axis, you can see where any given ventile from any country falls when compared to the entire population of the world.

For example, trace the line for Brazil, a country with extreme income inequality.

Brazil’s bottom ventile — that is, the poorest 5 percent of the Brazilian population, shown as the left-most point on the line — is about as poor as anyone in the entire world, registering a percentile in the single digits when compared to the income distribution worldwide. Meanwhile, Brazil also has some of the world’s richest, as you can see by how high up on the chart Brazil’s top ventile reaches. In other words, this one country covers a very broad span of income groups.

Now take a look at America.

Notice how the entire line for the United States resides in the top portion of the graph? That’s because the entire country is relatively rich. In fact, America’s bottom ventile is still richer than most of the world: That is, the typical person in the bottom 5 percent of the American income distribution is still richer than 68 percent of the world’s inhabitants.

Now check out the line for India. India’s poorest ventile corresponds with the 4th poorest percentile worldwide. And its richest? The 68th percentile. Yes, that’s right: America’s poorest are, as a group, about as rich as India’s richest.

Kind of blows your mind, right?

Now you might be wondering: How can there be so many people in the world who make less than America’s poorest, many of whom make nothing each year? Remember that were looking at the entire bottom chunk of Americans, some of whom make as much as $6,700; that may be extremely poor by American standards, but that amounts to a relatively good standard of living in India, where about a quarter of the population lives on $1 a day.

As Mr. Brankovic writes:

One’s income thus crucially depends on citizenship, which in turn means (in a world of rather low international migration) place of birth. All people born in rich countries thus receive a location premium or a location rent; all those born in poor countries get a location penalty.

It is easy to see that in such a world, most of one’s lifetime income will be determined at birth.

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

Giving Workers a Union Choice

More states consider right-to-work laws.

One of the under-appreciated fault lines in the U.S. economy is between the 22 "right-to-work" states and the rest of the country. The former have tended to do much better economically. Now some non-right-to-work states such as Indiana, Wisconsin and Michigan are thinking about joining this club that allows workers to opt-out of union membership.

Contrary to much union rhetoric, right-to-work laws don't ban or bust unions. They simply grant individual workers the right to join or not to join, even once a workplace is organized by a union. Workers who decline to join the union can't be forced to have dues taken out of their paycheck and thus used to finance union political campaigns. Most right-to-work states are in the South and West, and only Oklahoma has adopted this freedom to choose in the last 20 years.

Right-to-work states outperform forced-union states in almost every measurable category of worker well-being. A new study in the Cato Journal by economist Richard Vedder finds that from 2000 to 2008 some 4.7 million Americans moved from forced-union to right-to-work states.

The study also found that from 1977 through 2007 there was "a very strong and highly statistically significant relationship between right-to-work laws and economic growth." Right-to-work states experienced a 23% faster rise in per capita income over that period. The two regions that have lost the most jobs in recent years, the once-industrial Northeast and Midwest, are mostly forced-union states.

Indiana is a case study in the negative effects of forced unionism. Governor Mitch Daniels recently explained why his state lost a bid for a new Colgate factory that would have employed hundreds: "We did absolutely everything we could do. . . . We made an offer we believe was competitive in every other respect, but they [Colgate] want to be in a right-to-work state."

Mr. Daniels adds that the lack of a right-to-work law "does hold us back economically. There is no doubt about it." He estimates that when competing with Southern states for businesses, "a very large number—perhaps as many as a quarter—of the deals we don't get a shot at are for just this reason."

This damage has motivated Indiana Republicans, who now control both legislature chambers, to announce that they want to pass a right-to-work law. Unions immediately went to Defcon 1, Democrats are up in arms, and Republicans could yet buckle under this union pressure. Even Mr. Daniels, who has stood up to union opposition in the past, seems hesitant. He told the Indianapolis Star that right to work "may be worth a look," but he added it "is not on my agenda." He's worried that the issue so antagonizes unions that it could derail the rest of his legislative agenda.

We hope Republicans don't flinch. Right-to-work laws make states more economically competitive, but the bigger issue is about individual rights. Workers should have the right to join a union but also the right not to. Indiana and other states with new Republican majorities have a rare opportunity to pass a major reform that will reduce union power, help to attract new jobs, and liberate workers from union coercion.

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

Europe's Emissions Trading Scams

This isn't a market; it's merely designed to look like one.

Once again, Europe's Emissions Trading System has been beset by fraud and theft. The spot-trading market has been closed since January 19, after regulators discovered that hackers had broken into the system's electronic registries and stolen roughly €30 million worth of carbon allowances.

This marks the second time in the past year that carbon trading has been shut down. Last year, the U.N.'s carbon market halted for several days when authorities discovered that the Hungarian government had—legally—been reselling allowances that had already been used. In 2009 Europol reported that in certain countries, 90% of the ETS's trading volume was taken up by value-added-tax scams. Europe's system has also been plagued by smaller thefts since its founding in 2005, and some companies in the Third World have spewed pollutants simply to eliminate them and sell the carbon allowances to European companies.

So, is the ETS just unlucky? EU Climate Action Commissioner Connie Hedegaard defended the system last week, saying that "Just because someone robs a bank, you do not say the whole banking system doesn't work." Perhaps. But we doubt the Deutsche Börse, London Stock Exchange or NYSE wouldn't long survive if they had the kind of history of serial theft and fraud that has bedeviled carbon trading.

What makes the ETS different? The simplest explanation is that it isn't a financial exchange at all; it's merely designed to look like one. Its chief function is to serve as a political smokescreen. The trading system was set up to allow Europe's politicians to avoid the messy business of who was going to be allowed to pollute what. To make matters worse, it's in no one's particular interest that it work too well—not the businesses buying credits; not the governments, which would rather take the credit for being green without the economic costs of being too pure; and certainly not the fraudsters, who have used the trading system to reap millions in profits.

To borrow Ms. Hedegaard's image, if there's one bank in the neighborhood that keeps getting robbed, but has no alarms, locks, or note-tracking devices to keep it secure, you wouldn't ask why it kept being ripped off. You'd wondered whether it was really a bank at all.

Printed in The Wall Street Journal, page 13

 

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

After the Revolution, Economic Reform

Tunisian protesters' message was that governments stifle the younger generation's economic aspirations at their own peril.

By CARL SCHRAMM

The street protests in Tunisia and elsewhere in the region are momentous not just for the Arab world but have the potential to foreshadow a brighter economic future for the globe. The protesters' basic message is not to stifle the economic aspirations of the younger generation, especially one as well-educated as Tunisia's. Shackle them at your own peril.

While Arab governments correctly interpret this cry for change as predominantly driven by economic hardship, their responses are unfortunately misdirected. Kuwait is giving its citizens free food rations and a grant of $4,000. Other governments have announced that they, too, plan to allocate millions of dollars to the poor; and Arab leaders are rushing to set up a $2 billion fund to support their economies. These measures won't save them.

The policies of more of the same, even with augmented funds, do not create the necessary economic opportunity to meet the core challenge of the youth bulge. The battle for prosperity in Tunisia, Egypt, Algeria, Morocco, Jordan, Libya and Yemen will require an economic-entrepreneurial revolution, not just a political one.This is key not just for job creation and making the economy more dynamic. It is a catalyst for political freedom as well.

At the same time, the prospects for any successful economic transformation increase significantly when economic and political liberalization go hand in hand. The fact that the Tunisian people took a decisive step toward political freedom on their own initiative therefore matters greatly.

The region's necessary economic transformation will require more than the oft-cited integration into the global economy. As important as that is, it is no panacea. As far as Tunisia is concerned, it actually has some of those global linkages in place already, albeit in low-value-added sectors such as tourism and contract-manufacturing facilities.

View Full Image

 

Associated Press

Protestors hold a Tunisian flag as they are angry over joblessness, corruption and repression.

 

The real change required is a sustained increase in average productivity. And this means leveling the playing field for the most productive small firms in the Arab world.

In recent decades, economic gains in Tunisia, Egypt and elsewhere stemmed mostly from large, politically connected businesses. Such favoritism—trying to buy political support from society's existing elites by cutting them into the deals—may have seemed politically expedient, but it was economically destructive.

Under these circumstances, most small firms were forced to stay small. This contributed to high unemployment, particularly among the younger generation, estimated to be about 40% for college graduates in Tunisia. That is why talented young people often felt compelled to emigrate. Reversing this brain drain by encouraging these professionals, who have sharpened their business skills abroad, to return home, would be a tremendous boon to the region's economies. By abandoning nepotism, favoritism and, in some cases, outright corruption, governments would provide a healthy growth stimulus by itself.

Another promising avenue would be to establish a mechanism to get uncollateralized credit for those small-business owners who, by skill or by luck, have created the most productive job opportunities. That would fuel economic growth and undermine the corrupt old boys' comfortable monopolies. And it would make room for a new generation of entrepreneurs in areas such as food distribution, machining, construction, equipment and parts fabrication, retailing, power distribution, transportation, communications—and, yes, media.

It appears that new generation is more than ready for this challenge. The actions of the protestors in Tunisia and elsewhere exude courage, initiative, can-do spirit, self-confidence and self-motivation—precisely the qualities that constitute the essence of entrepreneurship.

None of this is to say that the transformation is going to be easy. After decades of stunted political development and economic mismanagement, any transition is by necessity messy. But if managed successfully, Tunisia could herald the beginnings of a transformative change that would rival the events some decades ago in Poland, when trade union strikes helped bring about the end of communism.

The developments in Tunisia are especially intriguing from an American perspective because they reconnect us with the revolutionary thrust of our country's very own roots and its original promise—that advancing economic opportunity and freedom of opinion don't just go hand in hand, but are our very American way to spread liberty.

Mr. Schramm is president and CEO of the Kauffman Foundation.

 

WSJ Econ Blog Feb 1, 2011
4:02 PM

IMF Warned of Egyptian Youth Jobless Rate Ahead of Protests

By Ian Talley

The International Monetary Fund warned of dangerously elevated unemployment levels in Egypt, especially highlighting high jobless youth rates, just two days ahead of thousands taking to the streets to protest the ruling government.

 

IMF managing director Dominique Strauss-Kahn Tuesday said such levels created a ticking “time bomb” that could politically explode in other countries. While he declined to comment specifically on the protests, the IMF chief said, “clearly the situation in Egypt is the kind of situation that could have been expected not only in Egypt, when you see the problem created by the high level of unemployment.” He was speaking at an event in Singapore.

The IMF expects nearly 10 million jobs are needed in Egypt — more than 12% of the country’s population — and nations such as Jordan, Morocco, Syria and Lebanon will require millions more.

“Unemployment remains too high,” and Egypt needs to “focus on labor-intensive growth,” said regional IMF officials Ratna Sahay and Alan MacArthur in  a Jan. 23 presentation at the Egyptian Center for Economic Studies in Cairo. “To make major inroads into unemployment will require tackling labor market inefficiencies,” they said.

The fund officials were in Egypt as part of an annual economic review of the country and their conclusions will likely play a large role in informing their report due out in coming weeks. According to the presentation, they stressed the problem of unemployment levels in that country and other oil-importing countries in the Middle East and North Africa, pointing to youth jobless rates topping 25% in Egypt, 30% in Tunisia and 21% in Lebanon.

Regulations and a dearth in skilled labor are constraining the Egyptian labor market, the IMF officials. The cost of firing is high and top private sector jobs are often filled by relatives or friends. Only Lebanon and Syria scored worse on the rigidity of labor markets in the region.

The officials said that economic restructuring of Egypt’s exchange rate policies, the financial sector, privatization and its monetary policy were already producing positive changes.

But the IMF team said challenges facing the country — as well as other Middle East oil importers — centered on creating jobs, preserving economic stability and raising competitiveness. In particular, the Egyptian government needs to reduce public debt, better manage its tax revenue and tackle spending inefficiencies. For example, its current distribution of petroleum subsidies meant the country’s richest received eight times more than Egypt’s poorest.

The government also must combat inflation, with the country facing one of the increases in large emerging countries.

Adding to its economic burdens, the IMF officials said Egypt faces a monetary policy dilemma as inflation picks up. Although down from June 2008 highs near 25%, the annual rise in consumer prices has still hit over 10% in recent weeks.

Strauss-Kahn said rising food prices could have “potentially devastating consequences,” and the IMF was ready to help Egypt.

  • WSJ February 1, 2011, 10:47 AM ET

World-Wide Factory Activity, by Country

By Phil Izzo

Global manufacturing started 2011 on a strong note with most countries in expansionary territory and strong gains in the U.S., U.K. and euro zone.

Just Greece and Australia remained in contractionary territory in January, according to national manufacturing purchase managers indexes compiled by Markit, the Institute for Supply Management and others. Asia also continued its factory-sector expansion, even as China’s official measure posted a slowing in growth.

While the manufacturing expansion is good news for the recovery, the reports also note inflationary pressures growing in most of the world as producers deal with higher input costs.

Manufacturing Activity, by Country

Click on the top of any column to resort the chart. Readings above 50 signal expansion.

Country   

Jan. PMI   

Dec. PMI   

Monthly Change   

Rate of Change   

Austria

60.3

57.7

2.6

Expanding Faster

Australia

46.7

46.3

0.4

Contracting Slower

Brazil

53.1

52.4

0.7

Expanding Faster

China

52.9

53.9

-1

Expanding Slower

Czech Republic

60.5

58.4

2.1

Expanding Faster

Euro Zone

57.3

57.1

0.2

Expanding Faster

France

54.9

57.2

-2.3

Expanding Slower

Germany

60.5

60.7

-0.2

Expanding Slower

Greece

42.8

43.1

-0.3

Contracting Faster

Hungary

54.7

54

0.7

Expanding Faster

India

56.8

56.7

0.1

Expanding Faster

Ireland

55.8

52.2

3.6

Expanding Faster

Italy

56.6

54.7

1.9

Expanding Faster

Japan

51.4

48.3

3.1

Expanding

Netherlands

57.5

57.5

0

Expanding at same rate

Poland

55.6

56.3

-0.7

Expanding Slower

Russia

53.5

53.5

0

Expanding at same rate

South Africa

54.6

51.7

2.9

Expanding Faster

South Korea

53.5

53.9

-0.4

Expanding Slower

Spain

52

51.5

0.5

Expanding Faster

Switzerland

60.5

61.2

-0.7

Expanding Slower

Taiwan

59.8

54.7

5.1

Expanding Faster

Turkey

57.2

56.4

0.8

Expanding Faster

U.K.

62

58.7

3.3

Expanding Faster

U.S.

60.8

58.5

2.3

Expanding Faster

Sources: WSJ Research

 ************R6

Some items from Ellenor Ostrom’s CV


“What Do People Bring Into the Game? Experiments in the Field about Cooperation in the Commons” (with Juan-Camilo Cardenas). Agricultural Systems 82(3) (December 2004): 307-26.

“Coping with Asymmetries in the Commons: Self-Governing Irrigation Systems Can Work” (with Roy Gardner). Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(4) (Fall 1993): 93-112

“Design Principles and the Performance of Farmer-Managed Irrigation Systems in Nepal” (with Paul Benjamin). In Performance Measurement in Farmer-Managed Irrigation Systems, ed. Shaul Manor and Jorge Chambouleyron, 53–62. Colombo, Sri Lanka: IIMI, 1993.


“Lab Experiments for the Study of Social-Ecological Systems” (with Marco Janssen, Robert Holahan, and Allen Lee).
Science 328(5978) (April 30, 2010): 613–17.

“Analyzing the Dynamic Complexity of Development Interventions: Lessons from an Irrigation Experiment in Nepal” (with Wai Fung Lam).
Policy Sciences 43(1) (March 2010): 1–25.

“Revising Theory in Light of Experimental Findings.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 73 (2010): 68–72.

“Trust and Reciprocity as Foundations for Cooperation” (with James Walker). In Whom Can We Trust?: How Groups, Networks, and Institutions Make Trust Possible, ed. Karen Cook, Margaret Levi, and Russell Hardin, 91–124. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2009.

“Trust in Private and Common Property Experiments” (with James Cox, James Walker, Antonio Jamie Castillo, Eric Coleman, Robert Holahan, Michael Schoon, and Brian Steed).
Southern Economic Journal 75(4) (April 2009): 957–75.

“Fifteen Years of Empirical Research on Collective Action in Natural Resource Management: Struggling to Build Large-N Databases Based on Qualitative Research” (with Amy Poteete). World Development 36(1) (2008): 176–95.


"Complexity of Coupled Human and Natural Systems” (with Jianguo Liu, Thomas Dietz, Stephen Carpenter, Marina Alberti, Carl Folke, et al.). Science 317(5844) (2007): 1513–16.

“Insights on Linking Forests, Trees, and People from the Air, on the Ground, and in the Laboratory” (with Harini Nagendra). Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 103(51) (2006): 19224-31. Winner of the 2006 PNAS Cozzarelli Prize for paper of outstanding scientific excellence and originality.

 

N Y Times January 28, 2011, 7:46 pm

The Wal-Mart Decade

I’ve been putting some material together for textbook revision, and found myself looking at European versus US productivity performance over the past couple of decades. I sort of knew the facts here, but this recent paper by Bart van Ark (pdf) seemed to me to make the points especially clearly, and I found myself rolling my own versions of some of his numbers.

To get some sense of productivity trends, van Ark uses a fairly fancy statistical technique (Hodrick-Prescott filter). But a simple 5-year moving average, to smooth out the business cycle, does about the same thing. Here’s productivity growth in the US and in “Europe” defined as the average of the 4 big economies since 1970:

Total Economy Database

European productivity grew faster than the US until the 1990s, mainly reflecting catchup; but America moved ahead in the late 1990s; the data suggest that the differential has leveled out since, so this may have been a one-time bulge.

And what was it about? Van Ark’s data point to a huge surge between 1995 and 2004 in US productivity, not so much in producing goods as in distributing them. And we know what that’s about: Wal-Mart and other big box stores.

I’m not denigrating these productivity gains. What’s interesting, though, is that if you’re looking for a story about the relative American revival from 1995 until recently, it’s not so much a broad, generic economy thing as it is a story of one particular innovation that for whatever reason — land use regulations? — Europe was slow to imitate.

 

Marginal Revolution  2-1-11

Five-year average productivity

Tyler Cowen

 
That is from Paul Krugman.  And from Krugman's source, Bart van Ark:

To conclude, there is good reason to adjust the long-term US productivity growth rate downwards.

January 29, 2011 at 07:07 AM in Economics | Permalink | Comments (23

 

 

Innovation Is Doing Little for Incomes

By TYLER COWEN
Published: January 29, 2011 N Y Times

 

MY grandmother, who was born in 1905, spoke often about the immense changes she had seen, including the widespread adoption of electricity, the automobile, flush toilets, antibiotics and convenient household appliances. Since my birth in 1962, it seems to me, there have not been comparable improvements.

David G. Klein

Of course, the personal computer and its cousin, the smartphone, have brought about some big changes. And many goods and services are now more plentiful and of better quality. But compared with what my grandmother witnessed, the basic accouterments of life have remained broadly the same.

The income numbers for Americans reflect this slowdown in growth. From 1947 to 1973 — a period of just 26 years — inflation-adjusted median income in the United States more than doubled. But in the 31 years from 1973 to 2004, it rose only 22 percent. And, over the last decade, it actually declined.

Most well-off countries have experienced income growth slowdowns since the early 1970s, so it would seem that a single cause is transcending national borders: the reaching of a technological plateau. The numbers suggest that for almost 40 years, we’ve had near-universal dissemination of the major innovations stemming from the Industrial Revolution, many of which combined efficient machines with potent fossil fuels. Today, no huge improvement for the automobile or airplane is in sight, and the major struggle is to limit their pollution, not to vastly improve their capabilities.

Although America produces plenty of innovations, most are not geared toward significantly raising the average standard of living. It seems that we are coming up with ideas that benefit relatively small numbers of people, compared with the broad-based advances of earlier decades, when the modern world was put into place. If pre-1973 growth rates had continued, for example, median family income in the United States would now be more than $90,000, as opposed to its current range of around $50,000.

Will the Internet usher in a new economic growth explosion? Quite possibly, but it hasn’t delivered very good macroeconomic performance over the last decade. Many of the Internet’s gains are fun — games, chat rooms, Twitter streams — rather than vast sources of revenue, and when there have been measurable monetary gains, they often have been concentrated among a small number of company founders, as with, say, Facebook. As for users, the Internet has benefited the well-educated and the curious to a disproportionate degree, but apparently not enough to bolster median income.

Beyond the income slowdown, there is a further worry: an increasing share of the economy consists of education and health care. That trend is not necessarily bad, but in these two areas, results are often hard to measure. If health care costs rise 6 percent in a year, for example, that counts as higher G.D.P., but how much is our health actually improving? It’s an open question. America spends more on health care than other countries, but those expenditures don’t seem to produce uniformly superior results. And while there have certainly been gains in medical treatment, we may be overvaluing them. In education, we are spending more each year, but test scores have stagnated for decades, graduation rates are down and America’s worst schools are disasters.

There is an even broader problem. When it comes to measuring national income, we’re generally valuing expenditures at cost, rather than tracking productivity in terms of results. In other words, our statistics may be deceiving us — by accepting, say, our health care and educational expenditures at face value. This theme has been emphasized by the PayPal co-founder Peter Thiel in his public talks and by the economist Michael Mandel in his writings. And I’ve stressed it in a recent e-book, “The Great Stagnation.”

Sooner or later, new technological revolutions will occur, perhaps in the biosciences, through genome sequencing, or in energy production, through viable solar power, for example. But these transformations won’t come overnight, and we’ll have to make do in the meantime. Instead of facing up to this scarcity, politicians promote tax cuts and income redistribution policies to benefit favored constituencies. Yet these are one-off adjustments and, over time, they cannot undo the slower rate of growth in average living standards.

It’s unclear whether Americans have the temperament to make a smooth transition to a more stagnant economy. After all, we’ve long thought of our country as the land of unlimited opportunity. In practice, this optimism has meant that we continue to increase government spending, whether or not we can afford it.

In the narrow sense, the solution to the stagnation of median income will not be a political one. And one of the hardest points to grasp about this quandary is that no one in particular is to blame. Scientific progress has never proceeded on an even, predictable basis, even though for part of the 20th century it seemed that it might.

Science should be encouraged with subsidies for basic research, as well as private charity, educational reform, a business culture geared toward commercializing inventions, and greater public appreciation for the scientific endeavor. A lighter legal and regulatory hand could ease the path of future innovations.

NONETHELESS, advancing discovery is not a goal to be reached by the mere application of will. Precisely because there is no obvious villain and no simple fix, and many complex factors behind success, science as a general topic doesn’t play a big role in American political discourse. When it comes to understanding our macroeconomic predicament, we often seem to be missing the point.

Until science has a greater impact again on average daily living standards, the political problem will be in learning to live within our means. Because neither major party seems to support a plausible path to fiscal balance, or to acknowledge how little control politicians actually have over future income growth, we unscientifically keep living in an age of denial.

Tyler Cowen is a professor of economics at George Mason University.

A version of this article appeared in print on January 30, 2011, on page BU4 of the New York edition.

 

MR  Feb 1 2011

Median-itis and The Great Stagnation

Tyler Cowen

Here is my NYT column from today, on themes relevant to The Great Stagnation.  I won't rehash this entire discussion, but I would like to focus on this one column excerpt:

From 1947 to 1973 — a period of just 26 years — inflation-adjusted median income in the United States more than doubled. But in the 31 years from 1973 to 2004, it rose only 22 percent. And, over the last decade, it actually declined.

I am noticing that some reviews or commentaries (and here) are citing per capita income growth as a response to my argument.  It is true that per capita income grows at a slower rate post-1973, but my argument is about the slowing down of median income growth and that is a much stronger shift.  The productivity data also tell a glum story.   

CPI bias can change those numbers in absolute terms (see comments from Russ Roberts), but it also changes the pre-1973 median income growth numbers and arguably more soThe gap remains and TGS refers to the living standard for the average person or household in the United States, not the total amount of innovation, which remains quite high.  They're just not innovations with the same trickle-down or broad-based effects as in an earlier era.

Kindle eBooks are themselves a good example.  It's a real improvement for a lot of us -- especially travelers -- but even the median reader, much less the median American, doesn't have a Kindle or buy eBooks.  As I argued in The Age of the Infovore, the big gains of late have gone to the extreme information-processors.  

I've seen in the MR comments (and elsewhere) a lot of anecdotal comparison of recent gains vs. earlier gains in technology.  Don't we now have this, don't we now have that, and so on.  Of course.  Median incomes have risen somewhat.  But, when it comes to the average household, the published numbers for median income are adding up and trying to measure those gains and it turns out their recent rate of growth really has declined.  Most serious researchers who work in this area use and accept these numbers as the best available (though they do not in general advocate my causal interpretation; see for instance Mark Thoma or Jacob Hacker).  

If the numbers for median income growth are low we ought to take that seriously, as does Scott Sumner.  We are not cheerleaders per se (BC: "I'm baffled why Tyler would focus on slight declines in American growth when the world just had the best decade ever."  Is it then wrong to focus on any other problems at all?  I also was one of the first people to make the "best decade ever" argument, which I still accept.)  Medians also matter for the political climate, even though the median earner is not exactly the median voter.  Adam Smith's welfare economics was basically that of the median, a point which David Levy has made repeatedly.

I'm also being called a "pessimist" a lot.  Yet in my view our current technological plateau won't last forever.  That's probably more optimistic than the Hacker-Pierson approach, which requires a Progressive revolution in economic policy (unlikely), although it is not more optimistic than denying the relevance of the numbers.

I'll soon blog some remarks on changing household size as another attempt to avoid confronting the facts about slow median income growth.

January 30, 2011 at 07:53 AM in Books, Data Source, Economics | Permalink | Comments (62)

 

The Kitchen Test

Tyler Cowen

Here is Paul Krugman, noting that innovations for the kitchen have slowed down.  He cites this earlier, mid-90s piece of his on kitchens, which I would have cited had I known about it.  His conclusion:

By any reasonable standard, the change in how America lived between 1918 and 1957 was immensely greater than the change between 1957 and the present.

As Krugman did in the mid-1990s, I now cook in a 1950s kitchen and it suits me fine.  I use the microwave reluctantly and when I first met Natasha, eight years ago, she and Yana thought it noteworthy that I did not know how to use the device at all.  I do not see that my cooking stands at a disadvantage.

Alexander J. Field has a long and very good piece on the evolution of kitchen technology.  He concludes:

Aside from the automatic dishwasher in the 1930s (which achieved significant penetration only beginning in the 1960s), the garbage disposer (introduced in the 1950s, but low penetration until the late 1960s) and the microwave oven in the 1970s, there have been no truly revolutionary kitchen appliances in the last eight decades.

Field makes good fun of the electric can opener and the electric carving knife.

Here is a related Krugman post on the 19th century.

N Y Times  January 31, 2011, 9:35 am

The Haves and the Have-Nots

By CATHERINE RAMPELL

12:51 p.m. | Updated Updated with additional explanation of how the chart controls for different costs of living around the world.

I had a review this weekend about “ The Haves and the Have-Nots,” a new book by the World Bank economist  Branko Milanovic about inequality around the world. My favorite part of the book was this graph, next to which I actually wrote “awesome chart” in the margin:

Branko Milanovic, “The Haves and the Have-Nots,” p. 116.

The graph shows inequality within a country, in the context of inequality around the world. It can take a few minutes to get your bearings with this chart, but trust me, it’s worth it.

Here the population of each country is divided into 20 equally-sized income groups, ranked by their household per-capita income. These are called “ventiles,” as you can see on the horizontal axis, and each “ventile” translates to a cluster of five percentiles.

The household income numbers are all converted into  international dollars adjusted for equal purchasing power, since the cost of goods varies from country to country. In other words, the chart adjusts for the cost of living in different countries, so we are looking at consistent living standards worldwide.

Now on the vertical axis, you can see where any given ventile from any country falls when compared to the entire population of the world.

For example, trace the line for Brazil, a country with extreme income inequality.

Brazil’s bottom ventile — that is, the poorest 5 percent of the Brazilian population, shown as the left-most point on the line — is about as poor as anyone in the entire world, registering a percentile in the single digits when compared to the income distribution worldwide. Meanwhile, Brazil also has some of the world’s richest, as you can see by how high up on the chart Brazil’s top ventile reaches. In other words, this one country covers a very broad span of income groups.

Now take a look at America.

Notice how the entire line for the United States resides in the top portion of the graph? That’s because the entire country is relatively rich. In fact, America’s bottom ventile is still richer than most of the world: That is, the typical person in the bottom 5 percent of the American income distribution is still richer than 68 percent of the world’s inhabitants.

Now check out the line for India. India’s poorest ventile corresponds with the 4th poorest percentile worldwide. And its richest? The 68th percentile. Yes, that’s right: America’s poorest are, as a group, about as rich as India’s richest.

Kind of blows your mind, right?

Now you might be wondering: How can there be so many people in the world who make less than America’s poorest, many of whom make nothing each year? Remember that were looking at the entire bottom chunk of Americans, some of whom make as much as $6,700; that may be extremely poor by American standards, but that amounts to a relatively good standard of living in India, where about a quarter of the population lives on $1 a day.

As Mr. Brankovic writes:

One’s income thus crucially depends on citizenship, which in turn means (in a world of rather low international migration) place of birth. All people born in rich countries thus receive a location premium or a location rent; all those born in poor countries get a location penalty.

It is easy to see that in such a world, most of one’s lifetime income will be determined at birth.

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

Giving Workers a Union Choice

More states consider right-to-work laws.

One of the under-appreciated fault lines in the U.S. economy is between the 22 "right-to-work" states and the rest of the country. The former have tended to do much better economically. Now some non-right-to-work states such as Indiana, Wisconsin and Michigan are thinking about joining this club that allows workers to opt-out of union membership.

Contrary to much union rhetoric, right-to-work laws don't ban or bust unions. They simply grant individual workers the right to join or not to join, even once a workplace is organized by a union. Workers who decline to join the union can't be forced to have dues taken out of their paycheck and thus used to finance union political campaigns. Most right-to-work states are in the South and West, and only Oklahoma has adopted this freedom to choose in the last 20 years.

Right-to-work states outperform forced-union states in almost every measurable category of worker well-being. A new study in the Cato Journal by economist Richard Vedder finds that from 2000 to 2008 some 4.7 million Americans moved from forced-union to right-to-work states.

The study also found that from 1977 through 2007 there was "a very strong and highly statistically significant relationship between right-to-work laws and economic growth." Right-to-work states experienced a 23% faster rise in per capita income over that period. The two regions that have lost the most jobs in recent years, the once-industrial Northeast and Midwest, are mostly forced-union states.

Indiana is a case study in the negative effects of forced unionism. Governor Mitch Daniels recently explained why his state lost a bid for a new Colgate factory that would have employed hundreds: "We did absolutely everything we could do. . . . We made an offer we believe was competitive in every other respect, but they [Colgate] want to be in a right-to-work state."

Mr. Daniels adds that the lack of a right-to-work law "does hold us back economically. There is no doubt about it." He estimates that when competing with Southern states for businesses, "a very large number—perhaps as many as a quarter—of the deals we don't get a shot at are for just this reason."

This damage has motivated Indiana Republicans, who now control both legislature chambers, to announce that they want to pass a right-to-work law. Unions immediately went to Defcon 1, Democrats are up in arms, and Republicans could yet buckle under this union pressure. Even Mr. Daniels, who has stood up to union opposition in the past, seems hesitant. He told the Indianapolis Star that right to work "may be worth a look," but he added it "is not on my agenda." He's worried that the issue so antagonizes unions that it could derail the rest of his legislative agenda.

We hope Republicans don't flinch. Right-to-work laws make states more economically competitive, but the bigger issue is about individual rights. Workers should have the right to join a union but also the right not to. Indiana and other states with new Republican majorities have a rare opportunity to pass a major reform that will reduce union power, help to attract new jobs, and liberate workers from union coercion.

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

Europe's Emissions Trading Scams

This isn't a market; it's merely designed to look like one.

Once again, Europe's Emissions Trading System has been beset by fraud and theft. The spot-trading market has been closed since January 19, after regulators discovered that hackers had broken into the system's electronic registries and stolen roughly €30 million worth of carbon allowances.

This marks the second time in the past year that carbon trading has been shut down. Last year, the U.N.'s carbon market halted for several days when authorities discovered that the Hungarian government had—legally—been reselling allowances that had already been used. In 2009 Europol reported that in certain countries, 90% of the ETS's trading volume was taken up by value-added-tax scams. Europe's system has also been plagued by smaller thefts since its founding in 2005, and some companies in the Third World have spewed pollutants simply to eliminate them and sell the carbon allowances to European companies.

So, is the ETS just unlucky? EU Climate Action Commissioner Connie Hedegaard defended the system last week, saying that "Just because someone robs a bank, you do not say the whole banking system doesn't work." Perhaps. But we doubt the Deutsche Börse, London Stock Exchange or NYSE wouldn't long survive if they had the kind of history of serial theft and fraud that has bedeviled carbon trading.

What makes the ETS different? The simplest explanation is that it isn't a financial exchange at all; it's merely designed to look like one. Its chief function is to serve as a political smokescreen. The trading system was set up to allow Europe's politicians to avoid the messy business of who was going to be allowed to pollute what. To make matters worse, it's in no one's particular interest that it work too well—not the businesses buying credits; not the governments, which would rather take the credit for being green without the economic costs of being too pure; and certainly not the fraudsters, who have used the trading system to reap millions in profits.

To borrow Ms. Hedegaard's image, if there's one bank in the neighborhood that keeps getting robbed, but has no alarms, locks, or note-tracking devices to keep it secure, you wouldn't ask why it kept being ripped off. You'd wondered whether it was really a bank at all.

Printed in The Wall Street Journal, page 13

 

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 2, 2011

After the Revolution, Economic Reform

Tunisian protesters' message was that governments stifle the younger generation's economic aspirations at their own peril.

By CARL SCHRAMM

The street protests in Tunisia and elsewhere in the region are momentous not just for the Arab world but have the potential to foreshadow a brighter economic future for the globe. The protesters' basic message is not to stifle the economic aspirations of the younger generation, especially one as well-educated as Tunisia's. Shackle them at your own peril.

While Arab governments correctly interpret this cry for change as predominantly driven by economic hardship, their responses are unfortunately misdirected. Kuwait is giving its citizens free food rations and a grant of $4,000. Other governments have announced that they, too, plan to allocate millions of dollars to the poor; and Arab leaders are rushing to set up a $2 billion fund to support their economies. These measures won't save them.

The policies of more of the same, even with augmented funds, do not create the necessary economic opportunity to meet the core challenge of the youth bulge. The battle for prosperity in Tunisia, Egypt, Algeria, Morocco, Jordan, Libya and Yemen will require an economic-entrepreneurial revolution, not just a political one.This is key not just for job creation and making the economy more dynamic. It is a catalyst for political freedom as well.

At the same time, the prospects for any successful economic transformation increase significantly when economic and political liberalization go hand in hand. The fact that the Tunisian people took a decisive step toward political freedom on their own initiative therefore matters greatly.

The region's necessary economic transformation will require more than the oft-cited integration into the global economy. As important as that is, it is no panacea. As far as Tunisia is concerned, it actually has some of those global linkages in place already, albeit in low-value-added sectors such as tourism and contract-manufacturing facilities.

View Full Image

 

Associated Press

Protestors hold a Tunisian flag as they are angry over joblessness, corruption and repression.

 

The real change required is a sustained increase in average productivity. And this means leveling the playing field for the most productive small firms in the Arab world.

In recent decades, economic gains in Tunisia, Egypt and elsewhere stemmed mostly from large, politically connected businesses. Such favoritism—trying to buy political support from society's existing elites by cutting them into the deals—may have seemed politically expedient, but it was economically destructive.

Under these circumstances, most small firms were forced to stay small. This contributed to high unemployment, particularly among the younger generation, estimated to be about 40% for college graduates in Tunisia. That is why talented young people often felt compelled to emigrate. Reversing this brain drain by encouraging these professionals, who have sharpened their business skills abroad, to return home, would be a tremendous boon to the region's economies. By abandoning nepotism, favoritism and, in some cases, outright corruption, governments would provide a healthy growth stimulus by itself.

Another promising avenue would be to establish a mechanism to get uncollateralized credit for those small-business owners who, by skill or by luck, have created the most productive job opportunities. That would fuel economic growth and undermine the corrupt old boys' comfortable monopolies. And it would make room for a new generation of entrepreneurs in areas such as food distribution, machining, construction, equipment and parts fabrication, retailing, power distribution, transportation, communications—and, yes, media.

It appears that new generation is more than ready for this challenge. The actions of the protestors in Tunisia and elsewhere exude courage, initiative, can-do spirit, self-confidence and self-motivation—precisely the qualities that constitute the essence of entrepreneurship.

None of this is to say that the transformation is going to be easy. After decades of stunted political development and economic mismanagement, any transition is by necessity messy. But if managed successfully, Tunisia could herald the beginnings of a transformative change that would rival the events some decades ago in Poland, when trade union strikes helped bring about the end of communism.

The developments in Tunisia are especially intriguing from an American perspective because they reconnect us with the revolutionary thrust of our country's very own roots and its original promise—that advancing economic opportunity and freedom of opinion don't just go hand in hand, but are our very American way to spread liberty.

Mr. Schramm is president and CEO of the Kauffman Foundation.

 

WSJ Econ Blog Feb 1, 2011
4:02 PM

IMF Warned of Egyptian Youth Jobless Rate Ahead of Protests

By Ian Talley

The International Monetary Fund warned of dangerously elevated unemployment levels in Egypt, especially highlighting high jobless youth rates, just two days ahead of thousands taking to the streets to protest the ruling government.

 

IMF managing director Dominique Strauss-Kahn Tuesday said such levels created a ticking “time bomb” that could politically explode in other countries. While he declined to comment specifically on the protests, the IMF chief said, “clearly the situation in Egypt is the kind of situation that could have been expected not only in Egypt, when you see the problem created by the high level of unemployment.” He was speaking at an event in Singapore.

The IMF expects nearly 10 million jobs are needed in Egypt — more than 12% of the country’s population — and nations such as Jordan, Morocco, Syria and Lebanon will require millions more.

“Unemployment remains too high,” and Egypt needs to “focus on labor-intensive growth,” said regional IMF officials Ratna Sahay and Alan MacArthur in  a Jan. 23 presentation at the Egyptian Center for Economic Studies in Cairo. “To make major inroads into unemployment will require tackling labor market inefficiencies,” they said.

The fund officials were in Egypt as part of an annual economic review of the country and their conclusions will likely play a large role in informing their report due out in coming weeks. According to the presentation, they stressed the problem of unemployment levels in that country and other oil-importing countries in the Middle East and North Africa, pointing to youth jobless rates topping 25% in Egypt, 30% in Tunisia and 21% in Lebanon.

Regulations and a dearth in skilled labor are constraining the Egyptian labor market, the IMF officials. The cost of firing is high and top private sector jobs are often filled by relatives or friends. Only Lebanon and Syria scored worse on the rigidity of labor markets in the region.

The officials said that economic restructuring of Egypt’s exchange rate policies, the financial sector, privatization and its monetary policy were already producing positive changes.

But the IMF team said challenges facing the country — as well as other Middle East oil importers — centered on creating jobs, preserving economic stability and raising competitiveness. In particular, the Egyptian government needs to reduce public debt, better manage its tax revenue and tackle spending inefficiencies. For example, its current distribution of petroleum subsidies meant the country’s richest received eight times more than Egypt’s poorest.

The government also must combat inflation, with the country facing one of the increases in large emerging countries.

Adding to its economic burdens, the IMF officials said Egypt faces a monetary policy dilemma as inflation picks up. Although down from June 2008 highs near 25%, the annual rise in consumer prices has still hit over 10% in recent weeks.

Strauss-Kahn said rising food prices could have “potentially devastating consequences,” and the IMF was ready to help Egypt.

  • WSJ February 1, 2011, 10:47 AM ET

World-Wide Factory Activity, by Country

By Phil Izzo

Global manufacturing started 2011 on a strong note with most countries in expansionary territory and strong gains in the U.S., U.K. and euro zone.

Just Greece and Australia remained in contractionary territory in January, according to national manufacturing purchase managers indexes compiled by Markit, the Institute for Supply Management and others. Asia also continued its factory-sector expansion, even as China’s official measure posted a slowing in growth.

While the manufacturing expansion is good news for the recovery, the reports also note inflationary pressures growing in most of the world as producers deal with higher input costs.

Manufacturing Activity, by Country

Click on the top of any column to resort the chart. Readings above 50 signal expansion.

Country   

Jan. PMI   

Dec. PMI   

Monthly Change   

Rate of Change   

Austria

60.3

57.7

2.6

Expanding Faster

Australia

46.7

46.3

0.4

Contracting Slower

Brazil

53.1

52.4

0.7

Expanding Faster

China

52.9

53.9

-1

Expanding Slower

Czech Republic

60.5

58.4

2.1

Expanding Faster

Euro Zone

57.3

57.1

0.2

Expanding Faster

France

54.9

57.2

-2.3

Expanding Slower

Germany

60.5

60.7

-0.2

Expanding Slower

Greece

42.8

43.1

-0.3

Contracting Faster

Hungary

54.7

54

0.7

Expanding Faster

India

56.8

56.7

0.1

Expanding Faster

Ireland

55.8

52.2

3.6

Expanding Faster

Italy

56.6

54.7

1.9

Expanding Faster

Japan

51.4

48.3

3.1

Expanding

Netherlands

57.5

57.5

0

Expanding at same rate

Poland

55.6

56.3

-0.7

Expanding Slower

Russia

53.5

53.5

0

Expanding at same rate

South Africa

54.6

51.7

2.9

Expanding Faster

South Korea

53.5

53.9

-0.4

Expanding Slower

Spain

52

51.5

0.5

Expanding Faster

Switzerland

60.5

61.2

-0.7

Expanding Slower

Taiwan

59.8

54.7

5.1

Expanding Faster

Turkey

57.2

56.4

0.8

Expanding Faster

U.K.

62

58.7

3.3

Expanding Faster

U.S.

60.8

58.5

2.3

Expanding Faster

Sources: WSJ Research

 

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 7, 2011

A Modest $500 Billion Proposal

My spending cuts would keep 85% of government funding and not touch Social Security or Medicare.

By RAND PAUL

After Republicans swept into office in 1994, Bill Clinton famously said in his State of the Union address that the era of big government was over. Nearly $10 trillion of federal debt later, the era of big government is at its zenith.

According to the Congressional Budget Office, this will be the third consecutive year in which the federal government is running a deficit near or greater than $1 trillion. The solution to the government's fiscal crisis must begin by cutting spending in all areas, particularly in those that can be better run at the state or local level. Last month I introduced legislation to do just that. And though it seems extreme to some—containing over $500 billion in spending cuts enacted over one year—it is a necessary first step toward ending our fiscal crisis.

My proposal would first roll back almost all federal spending to 2008 levels, then initiate reductions at various levels nearly across the board. Cuts to the Departments of Agriculture and Transportation would create over $42 billion in savings each, while cuts to the Departments of Energy and Housing and Urban Development would save about $50 billion each. Removing education from the federal government's jurisdiction would create almost $80 billion in savings alone. Add to that my proposed reductions in international aid, the Departments of Health and Human Services, Homeland Security and other federal agencies, and we arrive at over $500 billion.

My proposal, not surprisingly, has been greeted skeptically in Washington, where serious spending cuts are a rarity. But it is a modest proposal when measured against the size of our mounting debt. It would keep 85% of our government funding in place and not touch Social Security or Medicare. But by reducing wasteful spending and shuttering departments that are beyond the constitutional role of the federal government, such as the Department of Education, we can cut nearly 40% of our projected deficit and at the same time remove thousands of big-government bureaucrats who stand in the way of efficiency.

View Full Image

 

Images.com/Corbis

 

Examples of federal waste are more abundant than ever. For example, the Department of Energy's nuclear-weapons activities should be placed under the purview of the Department of Defense. Many of its other activities amount to nothing more than corporate handouts. It provides research grants and subsidies to energy companies for the development of new, cleaner forms of energy. This means nearly all forms of energy development here in the U.S. are subsidized by the federal government, from oil and coal to nuclear, wind, solar and biofuels. These subsidies often go to research and companies that can survive without them. This drives up the cost of energy for all Americans, both as taxpayers and consumers.

The Commerce Department is another prime example. Consistently labeled for elimination, specifically by House Republicans during the 1990s, one of Commerce's main functions is delivering corporate welfare to American firms that can compete without it. My proposal would scale back the Commerce Department's spending by 54% and eliminate corporate welfare.

My proposal would also cut wasteful spending in the Defense Department. Since 2001, our annual defense budget has increased nearly 120%. Even subtracting the costs of the conflicts in Iraq and Afghanistan, spending is up 67%. These levels of spending are unjustifiable and unsustainable. Defense Secretary Robert Gates understands this and has called for spending cuts, saying "We must come to realize that not every defense program is necessary, not every defense dollar is sacred or well-spent, and more of everything is simply not sustainable."

For those who take issue with any of the spending cuts I have proposed, I have two requests:

First, if you believe a particular program should be exempt from these cuts, I challenge you to find another place in the budget where the same amount can feasibly be cut and we can replace it.

Second, consider this: Is any particular program, whatever its merits, worth borrowing billions of dollars from foreign nations to finance programs that could be administered better at the state and local level, or even taken over by the private sector?

A real discussion about the budget must begin now—our economy cannot wait any longer. For 19 months, unemployment has hovered over 9%. After a nearly $1 trillion government stimulus and $2 trillion in Federal Reserve stimulus, the Washington establishment still believes that we can solve this problem with more federal spending and the printing of more money.

That's ridiculous, and the American people have had enough.

Many in Washington think that a one-year, $500 billion spending cut is too bold. But the attendees at the newly formed Senate Tea Party Caucus say, "Bring on the cuts! And then, bring on more!" My Republican colleagues say they want a balanced-budget amendment. But to have any semblance of credibility we must begin to discuss where we will cut once it passes. My proposal is a place to start.

Mr. Paul is a Republican senator from Kentucky.

 

 

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 7, 2011

Will Cuba Be the Next Egypt?

The most striking difference between the two countries is Internet access.

·         By MARY ANASTASIA O'GRADY

Developments in Egypt over the last two weeks brought Cuba to my mind. Why does a similar rebellion against five decades of repression there still appear to be a far-off dream? Part of the answer is in the relationship between the Castro brothers—Fidel and Raúl—and the generals. The rest is explained by the regime's significantly more repressive model. In the art of dictatorship, Hosni Mubarak is a piker.

That so many Egyptians have raised their voices in Tahrir Square is a testament to the universal human yearning for liberty. But it is a mistake to ignore the pivotal role of the military. I'd wager that when the history of the uprising is written, we will learn that Egypt's top brass did not approve of the old man's succession plan to anoint his son in the next election.

Castro has bought loyalty from the secret police and military by giving them control of the three most profitable sectors of the economy—retail, travel and services. Hundreds of millions of dollars flow to them every year. If the system collapses, so does that income. Of course the Egyptian military also owns businesses. But it doesn't depend on a purely state-owned economy. And as a recipient of significant U.S. aid and training for many years, the Egyptian military has cultivated a culture of professionalism and commitment to the nation over any single individual.

View Full Image

 

Associated Press

Cuban President Raúl Castro

 

In Cuba there are no opposition political parties or nonstate media; rapid response brigades enforce the party line. Travel outside the country is not allowed without state approval. If peaceful dissidents with leadership skills can't be broken, they are eventually exiled. Or they are murdered.

The most striking difference between Cuba and Egypt is access to the Internet. In a March 2009 Freedom House report on Internet and digital media censorship world-wide, Egypt scored a 45 (out of 100), slightly worse than Turkey but better than Russia. Cuba scored a 90, making it more Net-censored than even Iran, China and Tunisia. Cellphone service is too expensive for most Cubans.

Yet technology does somehow seep into Cuba. When Fidel took the life of prisoner of conscience Pedro Boitel in 1972 by denying him water during a hunger strike, the world hardly noticed. By contrast, news of the regime's 2010 murder of prisoner of conscience Orlando Zapata Tamayo hit the Internet almost immediately and was met with worldwide condemnation. The military dictatorship was helpless to contain the bad publicity.

In a similar fashion, when the Ladies in White—a group of wives, sisters and mothers of political prisoners—walking peacefully in Havana were roughed up by state security last year, the images were captured on cellphones and immediately showed up on the Web. It was more bad PR for the Castro brothers and their friends like Mexican President Felipe Calderón and Spanish President José Luis Zapatero.

Technology-induced international pressure is making the regime increasingly reluctant to flatten critics the old-fashioned way. In an interview in Argentina's Ambito Financiero on Jan. 27, internationally recognized Cuban blogger Yoani Sánchez said the "style" of state repression has shifted from aggressive arrests and long sentences to targeted attempts at defamation and isolation. Ms. Sanchez also said that uniformed police are "distancing themselves from the political theme, not by orders from above, but because they no longer want to be associated with the repression." Now, she said, the intimidation and arbitrary arrests are largely carried out by the secret police in civilian clothes.

The Americas in the News

Get the latest information in Spanish from The Wall Street Journal's Americas page.

A little more space has emboldened the population. Ms. Sánchez also said in the interview that she is "optimistic about the slow and irreversible process of interior change in Cubans. In that the citizen critic will grow, will have less fear, and will feel that the mask is increasingly unnecessary and that it doesn't any longer translate into privileges and subsidies."

Last week a leaked video of a Cuban military seminar on how to combat technology hit the Internet. It demonstrates the dictatorship's preoccupation with the Web. The lecturer warns about the dangers of young people with an appealing discourse sharing information through technology and trying to organize. Real-time chat, Twitter and the emergence of young leaders in cyberspace—aka "a permanent battlefield"—are perils outlined in the hour-long talk. The lecturer also shares his concerns about U.S. government programs that try to increase Internet access outside of officialdom on the island.

On Friday, the regime further displayed its paranoia by charging U.S. Agency for International Development contractor Alan Gross with spying. Mr. Gross has been in jail for 14 months for giving Cuban Jews computer equipment so they could connect with the diaspora.

With very limited access, Cubans are already using the Internet to share what has until now been kept in their heads: counterrevolutionary thoughts. If those go viral, even a well-fed military will not be able to save the regime. But for now, Cubans can only dream about the freedoms Egyptians enjoy as they voice their grievances.

Write to O'Grady@wsj.com

 

 

WSJ econ blog Feb 4, 2011
1:12 PM

Messy New Estimates Complicate Explanation for Unemployment Rate Drop

By Jon Hilsenrath

The January unemployment report was very noisy, not just because bad weather kept people at home. The Labor Department also incorporated unusually large revisions to its estimates of the size of the population which make it hard to offer a clear explanation for what caused a drop in the unemployment rate to 9%.

The Labor Department’s bean counters recalculate the size of the population every January. Those new counts, in turn, are used to come up with new estimates for how many Americans are employed, unemployed or not in the labor force. Because of the revisions, Labor Department officials are flashing warning signs to anybody trying to infer too much in the unemployment portion of the monthly jobs numbers.

The Labor Department — using updated Census Bureau data — determined that its 2010 estimates of the size of the population had been 347,000 too high, its estimates of overall employment in 2010 had been 472,000 too high and that its estimates of people who were unemployed or not in the labor force were also off.

The adjustment makes it hard to decipher the underlying trend in the levels of the labor force, employment and unemployment in January. The standard table which shows these levels in the report —  table A-1 — provides an imperfect comparison. The 2010 numbers in the table use older population estimates but January 2011 uses the new population estimate. (Apples to oranges.) That table implies there was a big increase in the number of people dropping out of the labor force in January and only a small increase in employment … not a good signal for the economy, and also not a reliable signal.

A supplemental table in the January jobs report which attempts to apply the new population estimates back to 2010,  Table C, shows a big increase in employment and a small increase in people leaving the labor force from December to January. But it doesn’t provide a clear picture of the trend in employment and unemployment levels either, says Jim Borbely, a Bureau of Labor Statistics economist. That’s because it piles all of the new, lower population and employment estimates to December 2010 rather than spreading them out among earlier months. This makes it look like there were big swings in these levels that might not have occurred all at once.

Mr. Borbely says it’s better to look at rates — the unemployment rate, the labor force participation rate, the employment-to-population ratio — for a clear picture. These rates are less likely to be distorted by new measures of population levels. Looking at rates, this is what you CAN say about the report:

–The jobless rate has fallen by 0.8 percentage points in just two months to 9%. The drop might overstate the improvement because some people are leaving the labor force, and thus are no longer being counted as unemployed, but it is nevertheless a move in the right direction;

–The employment-to-population rate, a raw measure of how many working-age Americans have jobs, has risen to 58.4% from 58.2% in November. That’s just a small improvement and is still lower than it was a year ago. With the population revisions, perhaps the improvement was a tenth of a percentage point better, the report shows.

–Americans are not flooding back into the labor force as they used to do after a recession ends. The labor force participation rate dropped to 64.2% in January, its lowest point since 1984. Demographic trends like early retirements and women leaving work are likely part of the story. In the long-run, a lower labor force participation rate is not good news because it will hold back economic growth (fewer people producing stuff) and it means the working population has a large portion of non-workers to support. Moreover, if people are dropping out of the labor force for good, it might mean there is less slack in the job market — and thus more inflationary pressure building — than commonly believed.

 

 

 

WSJ econ blog Feb 4, 2011
2:48 PM

Canada Labor Market Mocks America’s

By Michael Casey

The Canadian and U.S. labor markets are currently mirror images of each other, and that’s fostering a straightforward strategy for currency traders: Buy the dollar of the north, sell the dollar of the south.

 

At 7 a.m. EST, Canada’s statistics agency announced that the country’s economy added 69,200 jobs in January. That’s almost five times the forecast of 15,000. It’s also almost twice that of the 36,000 jobs expansion reported an hour and half later by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, a figure that was almost one-fourth the size of the consensus forecast of 136,000 jobs.

Canada’s population is one-ninth that of the United States. So its jobs gain could be said to be the equivalent of a 622,800 result for its giant southern neighbor. To find anything bigger than that in the BLS’s newly revised monthly data for the U.S. you have to go back to September 1983, when the resolution of a strike by AT&T workers contributed to a surge of 1,114,000 jobs in payrolls for the month.

It was a similarly contradictory result in the two countries’ unemployment numbers. Whereas the U.S. rate surprisingly fell to 9.0% from 9.4% in December, Canada’s rose to 7.8% from 7.6%. And much as the explanation for the falling U.S. jobless rate was ascribed to the fact that the number of people who counted themselves as part of the labor force had fallen, Canada’s increase was caused by a sharp expansion of 106,400 in its work force.

So in the United States, despondent job seekers are giving up the search while in Canada they are hopefully rejoining it. Might it also be the case that Americans are crossing the border to look for work in the north?

In response to this stark contrast between the two countries, the Canadian dollar rallied more than a cent to a 2 1/2-year high against its U.S. counterpart Friday. The U.S. dollar was last quoted at C$0.9896.

With Canadian Finance Minister Jim Flaherty and other officials lately giving strong signals that they won’t stand in the way of a rising Canadian dollar, buying it on Friday was a no-brainer for currency traders.

The jobs data raise the prospect that the Bank of Canada will at its March 1 meeting increase its benchmark overnight rate, which it has kept at 1.00% in its past three meetings. Compare that to the Federal Reserve, which hardly anyone expects to raise rates from their current near-zero level until well into the second half of the year. The carry between those rates is attractive to a currency trader.

The divergent job results aren’t a fluke.

Some of it has to do with luck. Canada’s exports are heavily concentrated in commodities whose prices are booming. As a comparatively smaller, open economy, Canada is more tapped into the healthier growth rates seen in Asia and the rest of the world than is the U.S., more driven by its domestic activity.

And some of the contrast in experiences has to do with policies that existed in the boom years before the 2008 financial crisis.

Canada’s stricter mortgage lending rules and tighter bank regulation kept its housing and financial sectors in check while the United States was consumed by a destructive real estate and credit bubble in the middle of the 2000s. This left the northern country less burdened by an overhang of unemployed construction workers, real estate agents and mortgage loan officers.

Still, the irony is that one reason Canada is doing so well is that it is tapping into a much-delayed rebound in growth in the south. The recovery in U.S. manufacturing (albeit a more or less jobless one, according to the BLS) was evident in strong data, such as this week’s business index from the Institute of Supply Management. And that’s helping Canada’s exporters.

The history of economic cycles tells us that the trajectories of the two countries’ economies should at some point converge. But for now, the gap is wide, even with the recovering in the U.S. And that will continue to underpin the Canadian dollar.

 

 

  • WSJ February 4, 2011, 5:46 PM ET

Sugar Taxes Would Hit Poor, Minorities

By Jon Hilsenrath

 New research by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago says that taxes and sweetened beverages — which many states are considering as a source of revenue — would hit the poor, minorities and less educated Americans disproportionately. Bottom line: A sugar tax might help reduce obesity and the health hazards that come with it, but it’s a highly regressive approach.

Below, is a table with key statistics.

Total Daily Calories From Sugar Sweetened Drinks, in %, Among Different U.S. Groups

All Americans

5.6

Black

6.2

White

5.6

Hispanic

6

Less than high school

7.4

High school

7.3

Some college

5.8

College graduate

3.3

 

 

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 5, 2011

Listening to the Shale Revolution

Often the only 'reform' needed is a plan to remove obstacles to innovation.

·         By HOLMAN W. JENKINS, JR.

With turmoil in the Middle East comes the inevitable spike in oil prices, topping $90 this week. Look for energy security to make one of its recurrent runs to the top of the national agenda. This time, though, we should listen to the shale gas revolution that has put an unexpected energy bonanza at our feet in places like New York, Pennsylvania and Ohio.

Any energy forecast a few years ago that failed to anticipate the shale boom and associated technological breakthroughs now mostly looks like a wasted effort. And that's the point.

Shale gas came painlessly into the world, though on paper the number of rich and powerful interests it upset would be nearly endless. Every owner of an oil well or coal mine or conventional gas well. Investors in the U.S. and Europe and Canada who spent billions building terminals to import liquefied natural gas (LNG). Investors in a long-planned pipeline from Alaska to the upper Midwest. Investors in the massive Russian Shtokman field, tipped for LNG exports to the U.S.

Just a few years ago, Russian leaders talked up the inevitability of a natural gas cartel more powerful than OPEC. Never mind. The U.S. last year topped Russia in natural gas production for the first time since 2001.

In 2003, then-Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan urged a rapid expansion of LNG imports to make up for a domestic shortfall. "We are not apt to return to earlier periods of relative abundance and low prices anytime soon," he said. Never mind. The U.S. is now building an LNG terminal all right, so it can export its growing gas bounty—nearly two Saudi Arabias' worth—to Asia.

Last month's stock-swap deal between BP and Russia's Rosneft might, a few years ago, have caused strategic jitters in Washington. Never mind. The Putin regime remains as odious as ever, but the balance of power already is perceptibly shifting away from the world's petrocrats to consumers, thanks to shale gas.

View Full Image

Getty Images

The shale gas revolution has been a surprise, in a sector where surprises are still permitted.

The organized interests whose world is being knocked for a loop by shale gas surely aren't happy about it. The quality on display here is freedom to innovate, also known as freedom to disrupt the rich and powerful who would prefer not to be disrupted. In the U.S., landowners enjoy mineral rights and are free to sell or lease those rights to drilling companies, whatever the neighbors might say. It wasn't the Exxons and BPs but smaller companies that figured out how to make shale gas pay.

Under U.S. labor law, these companies were free to take a chance on new workers without making a lifetime commitment. Also important, back in the 1970s and '80s, a series of deregulatory moves eliminated price and usage controls on natural gas, without which the business would never have been interesting to innovators and entrepreneurs. One company, Mitchell Energy, worked out how "slickwater" fracturing combined with horizontal drilling could free gas from dense shale rock previously uneconomical to develop. The firm's founder, George Mitchell, last year received the Gas Technology Institute's lifetime achievement award.

The U.S. shale boom has ignited a search elsewhere, from China to Central Europe. Poland alone is estimated to hold shale gas reserves equal to half of Europe's existing conventional reserves—a fact already altering the strategic balance between Europe and its soon-to-be-former energy overlord, Russia.

Europeans have also discovered, however, they lack some of America's institutional advantages, from private ownership of resources to flexible labor markets. In the U.S., says the Oil & Gas Journal, "Companies generally can develop shale plays located in the U.S. Midcontinent and East, where most land is owned privately, with minimal political wrangling. The fact that shale developments can cover entire counties means that royalties are spread among thousands of individual landowners, often aligning them with operators."

Before we wallow in self-congratulation, let's note the impossibility of equivalent transformations in other areas of American life. Our air traffic control system is controlled by government and has failed miserably to keep up with traffic growth. Our public schools are laboratories of stasis. Detroit is bound by a monopolistic labor regime from the 1930s. To touch on an especially sore point, federal and state regulation of health insurance has all but extinguished innovation in health insurance, even as government policy has made us more and more reliant on these third-party payers.

The shale gas revolution has been a surprise, in a sector where surprises are still permitted. Nobody "planned" it. There's a lesson here for every kind of reformer: Often the only plan needed is a plan to remove obstacles to innovation.

 

 

  • FEBRUARY 5, 2011

Ben Bernanke's '70s Show

Inflation is on the horizon, and now is the time for the Fed to head it off.

By ALLAN H. MELTZER

In the 1970s, despite rising inflation, members of the Federal Reserve's policy committee repeatedly chose to lower interest rates to reduce unemployment. Their Phillips Curve models, which charted an inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation, told them that inflation could wait and be addressed at a more opportune time. They were flummoxed when inflation and unemployment rose together throughout the decade.

In 1979, shortly after becoming Fed chairman, Paul Volcker told a Sunday talk-show audience that reducing inflation was the best way to reduce unemployment. He abandoned the faulty Phillips Curve thinking that unemployment was the enemy of inflation. And he told the Fed's staff that while he thought highly of their work, he did not find their inflation forecasts useful. Instead of focusing on near-term output and employment, he changed the Fed's policy to put more emphasis on the longer-term reduction of inflation. That required a persistent policy that President Reagan supported even in the severe 1982 recession.

We know the result: Inflation came down and stayed down. The Volcker disinflation ushered in two decades of low inflation and relatively steady growth, punctuated by a few short, mild recessions. And as Mr. Volcker predicted, the unemployment rate fell after the inflation rate fell. The dollar strengthened.

That was not unprecedented. The Phillips Curve often fails to forecast correctly. Spanish inflation has increased in the last year while the unemployment rate rose above 20%. Britain also has rising inflation and rising unemployment. Brazil lowered inflation and unemployment together. There are many other examples if only the Fed would look at them.

Throughout its modern history, the Fed has made several of the same policy mistakes repeatedly. Two are prominent now. It concentrates on near-term events over which it has little influence, and neglects the longer-term consequences of its operations. And it interprets its dual mandate as requiring it to direct all of its efforts to reducing unemployment when the unemployment rate rises. It does not have a credible long-term plan to reduce both current unemployment and future inflation, so it works on one at a time. This is an inefficient way to achieve a dual mandate. It failed totally during the Great Inflation of the 1970s. I believe it will fail again this time.

Commodity and some materials prices have increased dramatically in the past year. Countries everywhere face higher inflation. Despite the many problems in the euro area, the dollar has depreciated against the euro, a weak currency with many problems, suggesting that holders expect additional dollar weakness. Imports will cost more.

I believe it is foolhardy to expect businesses to absorb all the cost increases by holding prices unchanged. And loan demand has started to pick up, increasing the amount of money in circulation. It is a big mistake to expect that the U.S. will escape the inflation that is now rising throughout the world.

Because the Fed focuses on the near term, it tends to ignore changes in money-supply growth. This, too, is a mistake. Sustained inflation always follows increases in money-supply growth. Sustaining negative real interest rates (i.e., adjusted for inflation), as we have now, will cause this.

The Fed should make three changes. First, it should increase the short-term interest rate it controls to 1%, which would show that it is aware of the inflation risk and will act promptly to counteract it. Current low interest rates are an opportunity for the Fed to start reducing excess reserves.

Second, it should announce a specific, detailed plan that explains how it proposes to reduce about $900 billion of the more than $1 trillion banks continue to hold in excess of their legally required reserves.

Third, it should end QE2, its latest round of Treasury bond purchases. If, last November, the Fed had waited two more months before starting QE2, it would have known that a double-dip recession was not about to happen. Instead of waiting, the Fed responded to the cries coming from Wall Street.

Current slow growth and high unemployment is not mainly a monetary problem. The financial system has more than ample liquidity. Uncertainty about government policy is a much bigger problem. Businesses have had many reasons to be uncertain, to wait for a clearer outlook that would permit them to more accurately estimate future costs and returns to new investment. Better to hold cash and wait.

Until the 2010 election changed their view of the future, there was no way to know how much tax rates would increase, what new, costly regulations would stem from the president's health-care reforms, the Dodd-Frank financial reforms, and elsewhere. The election reduced these concerns by giving control of the House to a majority that does not share President Obama's vision that a good society should be directed and regulated from Washington. Last December, when Mr. Obama agreed to extend the Bush tax cuts, he showed that some improvement in outlook was justified. The economy responded.

What we need out of Washington now is spending reduction, lower corporate tax rates, and a three-year moratorium on new regulation. But perhaps most importantly, we need a new Fed policy to prevent 1970s-style inflation. Inflation is coming. Now is the time to head it off.

Mr. Meltzer is a professor of economics at Carnegie Mellon University's Tepper School of Business, a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise Institute, and the author of "A History of the Federal Reserve" (University of Chicago Press, 2003 and 2010).

 

  • Wsj FEBRUARY 5, 2011

Arab World Built Colleges, but Not Jobs

Unemployment, Broad Among Region's Angry Youth, Is High Among Educated

By DAVID WESSEL in Washington and CHIP CUMMINS in San'a, Yemen

The anger of demonstrators in Tunisia and Egypt runs, too, through 25-year-old Saleh Barek al-Jabri.

Mr. Jabri, the son of a Yemini bus driver, says he answered his government's call for young people to study petroleum engineering, enrolling in a course at Yemen's Hadhramaut University for Science and Technology. Officials visited his school to offer encouragement. An oil minister came through to promise jobs. Mr. Jabri excelled, finishing fifth in his class.

Days of Rage in Tunisia

View Slideshow

 

Mathias Depardon for The Wall Street Journal

Ayman Ghamouri, 20, is a student at Sfax University studying biotechnology. He hopes to go into business after graduation..

But after graduating last year, he has yet to find work. Classmates with family connections got what few jobs existed. Mr. Jabri moved to Yemen's capital, San'a, where he shares a single room with two other unemployed recent graduates.

"I had dreams," Mr. Jabri says. "They've all evaporated."

Protests erupting across the Middle East are fueled by frustrations ranging from the lack of political freedom to police brutality. But in countries wracked by protest and those that have remained peaceful, a common thread runs: Governments have expanded universities and educated a swelling cohort of youth, without laying the groundwork to employ them.

"Surprisingly," International Monetary Fund economists Yasser Abdih and Anjali Garg wrote recently, "unemployment in the [Middle East and North Africa] region tends to increase with schooling." In the U.S., the opposite is true.

In Egypt, where the region's protests are at their most pitched, the ranks of the college-educated have grown steadily in the past few decades. In 1990, according to World Bank, 14% of college-age Egyptians were enrolled; in 2008, 28.5% were. Egyptian schools expanded, and a crop of European universities opened campuses there. The Egyptian government doubled the funding for higher education in its 2007 five-year plan and sought international advice on revamping the system.

But a 300-page examination of higher education in Egypt by the World Bank and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, published last year, noted "a chronic oversupply of university graduates, especially in the humanities and social sciences," mixed with complaints from business employers that they couldn't find workers with the skills they needed.

View Full Image

 

Chip Cummins/The Wall Street Journal

Ahmed Issa in Yemen

 

In Egypt, it said, high-school graduates account for 42% of the work force—but 80% of the unemployed. One in every seven college graduates in Egypt, Jordan and Tunisia is unemployed; many more are overqualified for the jobs they have.

The twin forces of education and technology have interwined to create a new dynamic. Education has raised expectations and broadened world views. Technology—TV, the Internet, omnipresent mobile phones—has armed the young not only with a clear sense of how the rest of the world, particularly China, is changing, but also given them the wherewithal to create a movement that is now reshaping their countries.

None of this is a surprise to students here. A 2008 World Bank report on education reform in the region delicately noted that "the region has yet to create the necessary conditions to maximize the economic contribution of education to society." The consequences of that are only now becoming obvious to all.

Trying to provide schooling to the largest number of people, many Arab countries spent heavily on higher education.

View Full Image

 

Joel Millman/The Wall Street Journal

Ibrahim Taya in his apartment in West Amman, Jordan.

 

"The objective was to boost economic growth, boost employment and realize equity in society," says the World Bank's Mourad Ezzine, a former Tunisian education expert who worked on the report. "It didn't work out well. For two reasons. First, the education system delivered quantity, not quality…. And, second, on the economic side, the creation of employment to meet the profile of those graduates didn't happen. Why? Because the reforms in these countries did not go far enough, fast enough."

Differences between the Middle East and other developing economies the world are telling:

• Fertility rates stayed higher longer in the Middle East than in East Asia or Latin America. That means many more workers to employ. Over the past decade, labor forces in Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, Morocco, Syria and Tunisia have grown by 2.7%, faster than anywhere outside of Africa.

• Economies haven't grown nearly fast enough to absorb these new workers. Egypt, a country of about 80 million, would need 9.4 million jobs to employ the existing unemployed and new entrants to the labor force, the IMF estimates. That would take economic growth of nearly 10% a year, much faster than the 6% average of recent years.

• Unemployment among the young, of all education levels, is particularly pronounced. In Egypt, according to the most recent IMF data, overall unemployment was 8.9%—but stood at 25.4% among those under age 25, the IMF says. In Tunisia, overall unemployment was 14.2%; youth unemployment was 30.3%.

View Full Image

 

Mathias Depardon for The Wall Street Journal

Unemployed men play cards in a cafe in Sidi Bouzid, Tunisia. In December, a young man in the town burned himself to protest his poor prospects.

 

For decades, the safety valve for the region's jobless—including for Jordanian, Egyptian, Yemeni, Palestinian and other college grads—was to emigrate, either to the prosperous oil-producers of the Middle East or to Europe or the U.S. But some rich Middle East rich countries region grew fearful in the 1990s and 2000s that they were importing potential unrest, so they replaced Middle Eastern immigrants with workers from Asia.

For educated workers without jobs, the other safety value was to Europe or the U.S. Lebanon's biggest export, it is sometimes said, is white-collar workers. Indeed, one reason to get a college degree for many is that it was seen as ticket to a job in another country.

Mohamed Refaat, a 24-year-old Egyptian who followed his brother to the U.S. in 2008, is living in Queens, N.Y., and working toward a master's degree in finance at Brooklyn College. He is applying for jobs at Merrill Lynch & Co., Goldman Sachs Group Inc. and the United Nations. "You don't have to be educated there," Mr. Refaat complains about his hometown, 30 minutes outside of Cairo. "It's not worth your skill. It's all about the connections."

Mr. Refaat worked as a financial analyst at the Egyptian stock market, but says he hit a ceiling there after only one year on the job. "Every morning I would wake up and research credit ratings," he says. "And it was all about the U.S. I dreamed of coming to America."

View Full Image

 

Philip Montgomery for The Wall Street Journal

Mohamed Refaat at the Egypt protests in Times Square Friday in New York. N.Y.

 

But for many of Mr. Refaat's counterparts, the global recession of the late 2000s closed an escape valve for Egypt.

By almost every measure, the disaffection among the young in Egypt was even greater than in neighboring countries. In survey of 2,000 people in the Middle East between 18 and 24 by public-relations firm ASDA'A Burson Marsteller, released last year, two-thirds said their countries were moving in the right direction. In Egypt, only 26% did.

While China and other booming economies were cultivating private sectors, Egypt clung stubbornly to a state-dominated model. Outside of agriculture, 70% of Egyptian workers work for the government. Few college grads sought, or even were offered, courses aimed at landing private-sector jobs.

The number of graduates overwhelmed the government's capacity to hire, leaving many of them with few options. The "dominant role of the public sector as an employer"—particularly in Egypt, but throughout the region—has inflated the graduates' wage expectations, put a premium on diplomas over useful skills and diverted talented workers from what might have been more dynamic private-sector enterprises, the IMF says.

Amid the recent unrest, governments across the region have announced measures to create economic opportunities. Earlier this week, Yemen promised to hire more college graduates for government work, among other measures.

In Yemen, Ahmed Issa majored in French at Dhamar University, near his home region of Wasab, in the central western part of the country. He was the first in his family to go to college. After graduating in 2005, he applied for a civil service job.

"Until now, no job," he says. Mr. Issa lives with distant, better-off relatives, does occasional electronics-repair work and gets a little money from an older brother, who after a 12-year job hunt, finally found work as an electrical engineer earlier this year.

Mr. Issa says he isn't uncomfortable, but is angry that he can't find work and start a family. He says protests in Tunisia and Egypt inspired him, but he didn't attend protests.

In Amman, Jordan, Ibrahim Taya is the youngest of 12 born to Palestinian refugees. Mr. Taya, 33 years old, didn't go to college, but took technical training courses, first by correspondence in Jordan and then by going to Canada and China to learn how to maintain pieces of equipment.

View Full Image

 

Today, he is unemployed and seething. For about a dozen years, he bounced around, working as a technician for mobile-phone networks in Sudan, Morocco, Egypt, Saudi Arabia and Iraq. He returned to Jordan in 2008, started a business that collapsed, he says, when a partner absconded with company funds. He started another last year.

The second company grew, eventually employing 21, he said. But it got whipsawed by the global recession and, by his account, demands for kickbacks from companies to which he was trying to sell. After blowing through all his savings, he laid off the workers and shut the company.

The contrast between his life and those of his older brothers is striking. Four received military-sponsored university scholarships. One became a internist, and found work in Saudi Arabia; another other served as an eye doctor for the Jordanian Army and then began his own practice. A third taught high school in Saudi Arabia, and the fourth became a computer programmer.

Today, Mr. Taya is on the streets of Amman with other protestors. He says he dreams of a "miracle—like they have in Egypt."

—Joel Millman in Amman, Jordan, and Mary Pilon in New York contributed to this article.

Write to David Wessel at capital@wsj.com and Chip Cummins at chip.cummins@wsj.com

 

·         Wsj FEBRUARY 7, 2011

A License to Shampoo: Jobs Needing State Approval Rise

  •  

By STEPHANIE SIMON

Amid calls for shrinking government, lawmakers across the country are vowing to cut regulations that crimp economic growth. President Barack Obama recently said it's time to root out laws that "are just plain dumb."

Tell that to the cat groomers, tattoo artists, tree trimmers and about a dozen other specialists across the country who are clamoring for more rules governing small businesses.

Rush Jagoe for The Wall Street Journal

Licensed florist Monique Chauvin in Louisiana.

They're asking to become state-licensed professionals, which would mean anyone wanting to be, say, a music therapist or a locksmith, would have to pay fees, apply for a license and in some cases, take classes and pass exams. The hope is that regulation will boost the prestige of their professions, provide oversight and protect consumers from shoddy work.

But economists—and workers shut out of fields by educational requirements or difficult exams—say licensing mostly serves as a form of protectionism, allowing veterans of the trade to box out competitors who might undercut them on price or offer new services.

"Occupations prefer to be licensed because they can restrict competition and obtain higher wages," said Morris Kleiner, a labor professor at the University of Minnesota. "If you go to any statehouse, you'll see a line of occupations out the door wanting to be licensed."

While some states have long required licensing for workers who handle food or touch others—caterers and hair stylists, for example—economists say such regulation is spreading to more states for more industries. The most recent study, from 2008, found 23% of U.S. workers were required to obtain state licenses, up from just 5% in 1950, according to data from Mr. Kleiner. In the mid-1980s, about 800 professions were licensed in at least one state. Today, at least 1,100 are, according to the Council on Licensure, Enforcement and Regulation, a trade group for regulatory bodies. Among the professions licensed by one or more states: florists, interior designers, private detectives, hearing-aid fitters, conveyor-belt operators and retailers of frozen desserts.

At a time of widespread anxiety about the growth of government, the licensing push is meeting pockets of resistance, including a move by some legislators to require a more rigorous cost-benefit analysis before any new licensing laws are approved. Critics say such regulation spawns huge bureaucracies including rosters of inspectors. They also say licensing requirements—which often include pricey educations—can prohibit low-income workers from breaking in to entry-level trades.

Texas, for instance, requires hair-salon "shampoo specialists" to take 150 hours of classes, 100 of them on the "theory and practice" of shampooing, before they can sit for a licensing exam. That consists of a written test and a 45-minute demonstration of skills such as draping the client with a clean cape and evenly distributing conditioner. Glass installers, or glaziers, in Connecticut—the only state that requires such workers to be licensed—take two exams, at $52 apiece, pay $300 in initial fees and $150 annually thereafter.

California requires barbers to study full-time for nearly a year, a curriculum that costs $12,000 at Arthur Borner's Barber College in Los Angeles. Mr. Borner says his graduates earn more than enough to recoup their tuition, though he questions the need for such a lengthy program. "Barbering is not rocket science," he said. "I don't think it takes 1,500 hours to learn. But that's what the state says."

Regulators in many states say the educational requirements are developed in consultation with industry experts and stress critical skills like sanitation and safety. A shampoo specialist in Texas, for instance, learns about neck anatomy and must practice skills such as regulating water temperature.

"There's a lot of different things that go into it," says Elizabeth Perez, the state's cosmetology program manager.

But critics say the licensing push is restricting job growth at a time when the U.S. can scarcely afford it. The service sector—which is the focus of many licensing laws—accounts for three-quarters of gross domestic product and most job growth in the U.S., according to McKinsey Global Institute, a research arm of McKinsey & Co. In a coming report, the institute will call for an aggressive effort to root out "unnecessary regulatory barriers that limit competition in pockets of the economy."

View Full Image

 

Mr. Kleiner, of the University of Minnesota, looked at census data covering several occupations that are regulated in some states but not others, including librarians, nutritionists and respiratory therapists. He found that employment growth in those professions was about 20% greater, on average, in the unregulated states between 1990 and 2000.

Licensing can also drive up costs to consumers. Licensed workers earn, on average, 15% more than their unlicensed counterparts in other states—a premium that may be reflected in their prices, according to a study published by the National Bureau of Economic Research and conducted by Mr. Kleiner and Alan Krueger, an economist at Princeton University.

Mr. Kleiner estimates that across the U.S. economy, occupational licensing adds at least $116 billion a year to the cost of services, which amounts to about 0.1% of total consumer spending. In a look at dentistry, Mr. Kleiner found that the average price of dental services rose 11% when a state made it more difficult to get a dental license.

State regulators say licensing is vital to protect the health and safety of citizens, and industry experts generally agree that certain professions should be monitored. Inept or untrained electricians or tree-trimmers, for example, could put innocent bystanders in danger. Acupuncturists, tattoo artists and massage therapists can potentially inflict more direct harm.

However, in many service trades, licensure "is totally out of control," says Charles Wheelan, a lecturer in public policy at the University of Chicago. He says the marketplace might be a better judge than the government of whether a barber or a yoga instructor is competent. "It's fairly easy for you to tell whether you've gotten a bad haircut or not, and if quality turns out to be bad, it's not a big social problem," says Mr. Wheelan.

"Who cares if [a bouquet] is color-coordinated?" says Monique Chauvin, a licensed florist in Louisiana, where would-be flower arrangers have to pass a written exam with questions on plant names and complimentary colors. "If you like it, you like it."

When a trade group does succeed in getting a licensing law passed, it sometimes exempts existing workers from the testing requirements. In Michigan, for instance, it will soon be a felony to practice massage without a license. Newcomers to the field must take 500 hours of classes and pass an exam to get that license. But a grandfather clause exempts most current massage therapists, including those who may never have taken a class at an accredited school.

View Full Image

Michal Czerwonka for The Wall Street Journal

Arthur Borner, center, checks a student's work at Arthur Borner's Barber College in Los Angeles.

 

Karen Armstrong, a massage therapist and chair of the Michigan Board of Massage Therapy, acknowledges that some ill-trained therapists will get licensed because of the grandfather clause. But since new entrants to the field will be better-educated, the standards of the profession will rise over time and consumers will get better care, she says.

Plus, she says, so many other trades are now licensed that massage therapists risked being relegated to second-class status if they didn't have their own state regulatory structure: "Not being licensed really puts our profession back behind a lot of other professions."

But whether licensing guarantees better-quality work is an open question. Several academic studies in the 1970s and '80s found that licensure boosted quality in professions such as dentistry, optometry, plumbing and real-estate sales. More recent studies have found no evidence that licensing improves the quality of teachers or mortgage brokers.

It's harder to measure quality in more subjective fields such as interior design or hair styling. But a look at consumer complaints about manicurists suggests licensing doesn't necessarily correlate with quality.

Alabama has perhaps the strictest licensing requirements in the nation: 750 hours of schooling and a written and practical exam. The state gets, on average, four public complaints a year about poor service, according to the Alabama Board of Cosmetology.

Connecticut, which doesn't require manicurists to get licenses, has averaged just six complaints a year to the state over the past five years. Two-thirds of those complaints are about gift certificates that aren't honored, according to data from the consumer protection division of the state attorney general's office.

Dusty Brummitt, a locksmith in Enid, Okla., says a new state law licensing his trade ensures the public gets quality work. Anyone who wants to be a locksmith must now prove he's in the U.S. legally, submit to a criminal background check, pay fees of up to $350 a year and pass a 50-question exam. Just 32% of applicants pass the locksmith exam, state data show.

Mr. Brummitt says the law has "gotten rid of about 90% of the scammers in our state" since it took effect in 2007.

But it's unclear how many scammers there were. The consumer-protection unit of the state attorney general's office received just two complaints about locksmiths in more than a decade—one in 2006, the year before the law took effect, and one in 2008, the year after, according to Tom Bates, who runs the division. Three applicants for licenses were rejected because of criminal history.

Mr. Brummitt says licensure wasn't intended to stifle competition. But he acknowledges that in some Oklahoma cities, the requirements have prompted immigrant entrepreneurs and retirees who did the work as a hobby—and who often undercut traditional locksmiths on price—to drop out of the trade. As a result, he said, some veteran locksmiths, who didn't have to pass the exam because they were grandfathered in, have "definitely seen an increase in business."

Cracking down on unlicensed workers generally falls to state regulatory agencies. Texas appropriated $151 million this fiscal year to regulate scores of occupations though independent boards and a state agency with about 400 employees. Colorado's Department of Regulatory Agencies oversees more than 70 occupations, including hunting guides and kick-boxers.

In Kentucky, the Board of Hairdressers and Cosmetologists has eight full-time inspectors who spend much of their time responding to anonymous tips about unlicensed manicurists. The inspectors rarely catch the alleged offenders, says Charles Lykins, the board's administrator, because "they take off running."

Mr. Lykins says it's in the public's interest to insist manicurists are well-trained. "Have you ever had a nail fungus? It's terrible," he says. "That's why we're there."

All this enforcement doesn't necessarily cost state taxpayers. Many states require their regulatory agencies to cover all their expenses from licensing fees.

Some agencies even turn a profit, which can be used to subsidize other state services. Over the past two years, Connecticut's general fund made nearly $21 million on licensing fees, after accounting for the cost of running the state's primary regulatory agency. California's general fund borrowed $96.5 million from its regulatory bodies' ample reserves in fiscal year 2008-9.

Still, some critics see a broader cost to the economy. It's tough for workers to move around the country, for example, when each state has a different list of jobs that require licenses—and a different set of standards to pass. More than 1,100 professions require a license in at least one state, but only about 60 trades are licensed in every state, according to the Council on Licensure, Enforcement and Regulation.

Florida for years required anyone marketing their services as "interior design" to get a license that called for six years of education and apprenticeship and a two-day exam. That requirement stunned Barbara Vanderkolk Gardner, a mostly self-taught designer who worked on luxury homes in New Jersey—no license required—and wanted to open a practice in Florida. If clients wanted to hire her to pick out pillows, paints and furnishings, Ms. Gardner says, she couldn't understand why the state would object: "I view myself as an artist, and I don't think art needs to be licensed."

Ms. Gardner worked with the Institute for Justice, a nonprofit libertarian law firm, to sue the Florida regulatory body in charge of interior design in U.S. District Court in Tallahassee, claiming the law violated their First Amendment rights to call themselves interior designers. A federal judge last year struck down the licensing law for residential designers. But the court upheld a requirement for commercial interior design, holding that the state had a rational basis for protecting the public from inept design, which could create safety hazards.

Ms. Gardner says her residential business is now flourishing in Sarasota, Fla., but she remains frustrated that she has to turn down jobs designing offices.

In Ohio, dieticians, athletic trainers and boxing promoters are among the professions that require licenses. If Kimberly Raisanen has anything to say about it, cat groomers might one day make it onto the list, too. Ms. Raisanen, a groomer in Fairview Park, Ohio, helped found the Professional Cat Groomers Association of America in 2008 to establish better education standards for the animal specialists who trim, clip, style and fluff felines.

The association has established written tests and a hands-on exam that helps determine which members of the trade are "worthy of being called a certified master cat groomer," Ms. Raisanen says.

But the group would like to go further. As soon as she can build up her organization, Ms. Raisanen says she'd like to begin lobbying Ohio and other states to license cat groomers, requiring anyone entering the trade to first prove his or her competency. Regulation, she says, would ensure "you are educated before you put a cat on that table."

Write to Stephanie Simon at stephanie.simon@wsj.com

  • WSJ FEBRUARY 5, 2011

Treasury Report Steps Up Criticism on Yuan's Level

By IAN TALLEY

WASHINGTON—The U.S. Treasury refrained from labeling China a currency manipulator but took a tougher line than in past years, saying the yuan is "substantially undervalued," warning "progress thus far is insufficient and that more rapid progress is needed.''

The Treasury's much-awaited report on China's currency reform steps up the rhetorical heat from the last update in July, which merely called the yuan "undervalued" instead of "substantially undervalued."

The Treasury is required to review twice a year whether China and other nations are manipulating their currencies. Such a declaration against China could have major ramifications for the international financial system as it could set off a trade war between the U.S. and its largest trading partner. The U.S. so far has stopped short of calling China a currency manipulator, and instead has used speeches and diplomacy to pressure the country to free its grip on the currency's value.

Chinese President Hu Jintao, during his Washington visit last month, said China was committed to exchange-rate reform. Since China announced last June that it would restart a program to make its currency more flexible, the yuan has appreciated around 3.7% against the dollar.

The report is likely to disappoint many U.S. lawmakers. With U.S. manufacturers complaining their products are being outsold by Chinese goods made at a cheaper cost, helped by an exchange rate they say is kept unfairly low, lawmakers wanted Treasury to name Beijing a currency manipulator and are threatening to pass punitive legislation. The Obama administration held up publishing the report until after Mr. Hu's visit. Legislators had called for the administration to press Mr. Hu on the exchange rate.

"It's as plain as the nose on your face that China manipulates its currency. It's just as plain that the only way to address this problem is for Congress to act," said Sen. Charles Schumer, (D., N.Y.), a lead critic of China's exchange rate policy, on Friday. Senate Finance Committee Chairman Max Baucus (D., Mont.) also criticized the administration for not labeling Beijing a currency manipulator. "China has been given a free pass on its currency practices for far too long," he said, adding that Congress needed to hold its largest trading partner to account.

Pressures on China's economy may help to drive that change. "It is in China's interest to allow the nominal exchange rate to appreciate more rapidly, both against the dollar and against the currencies of its other major trading partners," the Treasury said. Without greater flexibility, Beijing risks fueling excessively rapid growth of credit, and creating upward pressure on property and equity prices, which could threaten growth, it said.

Including inflation, the Treasury estimates the yuan's move is equivalent to an annual rate of 10% a year. China has also started relaxing restraints on the use of the yuan. The Treasury said these reforms will over time "contribute to a more market-determined exchange rate."

The undervalued yuan is also harming other emerging-nation economies, which could help the U.S. in its negotiations at the Group of 20 nations conference later this month. Countries such as Brazil, which have more open exchange rate policies, are dealing with a surge in investment that threatens to overheat their economies, the Treasury said, leading in some cases to over-valued exchange rates.

Despite the often-fierce rhetoric, no key lawmaker has introduced a bill trying to punish China for how it manages the yuan since Republicans took over the house. Big U.S. companies have warned against sparking a trade war with China, saying it would be more productive to protect their interests in other areas, such as defending intellectual property rights.

Eswar Prasad, a Cornell University economist and former China expert at the International Monetary Fund, said the Treasury's approach is constructive and avoids bringing "things to a boil." The report, "takes a carefully calibrated approach to Chinese currency policy, conveying a clear message on the need for more currency flexibility but without using language that would damage relations with China," Mr. Prasad said

The Treasury said it would continue to closely monitor yuan appreciation.

The report studied ten countries' exchange rate policies that account for over three quarters of U.S. trade.

—Luca Di Leo contributed to this article.

 

 

****************R8